Birth Control

Halliday G. Sutherland

This page copyright © 2003 Blackmask Online.

http://www.blackmask.com

  • CHAPTER I. THE ESSENTIAL FALLACIES OF MALTHUSIAN TEACHING
  • CHAPTER II. THE FALSE DEDUCTIONS CONCERNING POVERTY
  • CHAPTER III. HIGH BIRTH-RATES NOT THE CAUSE OF HIGH DEATH-RATES
  • CHAPTER IV. HOW RELIGION AFFECTS THE BIRTHRATE
  • CHAPTER V. IS THERE A NATURAL LAW REGULATING THE PROPORTION OF BIRTHS AND DEATHS?
  • CHAPTER VI. THE FALLING BIRTH-RATE IN ENGLAND: ITS CAUSES
  • CHAPTER VII. THE EVILS OF ARTIFICIAL BIRTH CONTROL
  • CHAPTER VIII. THE RELIGIOUS ARGUMENT AGAINST BIRTH CONTROL
  • CHAPTER IX. THE TEACHING OF THE CATHOLIC CHURCH ON BIRTH CONTROL
  • E-text prepared by the Distributed Proofreaders

    BIRTH CONTROL

    A Statement of Christian Doctrine against the Neo-Malthusians

    BY

    HALLIDAY G. SUTHERLAND, M.D. (Edin.)

    CHAPTER I. THE ESSENTIAL FALLACIES OF MALTHUSIAN TEACHING

    Section 1. MALTHUS AND THE NEO-MALTHUSIANS

    Birth control, in the sense of the prevention of pregnancy by chemical, mechanical, or other artificial means, is being widely advocated as a sure method of lessening poverty and of increasing the physical and mental health of the nation. It is, therefore, advisable to examine these claims and the grounds on which they are based. The following investigation will prove that the propaganda throughout Western Europe and America in favour of artificial birth control is based on a mere assumption, bolstered up by economic and statistical fallacies; that Malthusian teaching is contrary to reason and to fact; that Neo-Malthusian practices are disastrous alike to nations and to individuals; and that those practices are in themselves an offence against the Law of Nature, whereby the Divine Will is expressed in creation.

    (a) Malthus

    The Rev. Thomas Malthus, M.A., in 1798 published his Essay on the Principle of Population. His pamphlet was an answer to Condorcet and Godwin, who held that vice and poverty were the result of human institutions and could be remedied by an even distribution of property. Malthus, on the other hand, believed that population increased more rapidly than the means of subsistence, and consequently that vice and poverty were always due to overpopulation and not to any particular form of society or of government. He stated that owing to the relatively slow rate at which the food supply of countries was increased, a high birth-rate [1] inevitably led to all the evils of poverty, war, and high death-rates. In an infamous passage he wrote that there was no vacant place for the superfluous child at Nature's mighty feast; that Nature told the child to be gone; and that she quickly executed her own order. This passage was modified in the second, and deleted from the third edition of the Essay. In later editions he maintained that vice and misery had checked population, that the progress of society might have diminished rather than increased the “evils resulting from the principle of population,” and that by “moral restraint” overpopulation could be prevented. As Cannan has pointed out, [2] this last suggestion destroyed the force of the argument against Godwin, who could have replied that in order to make “moral restraint” universal a socialist State was necessary. In order to avoid the evils of overpopulation, Malthus advised people not to marry, or, if they did, to marry late in life and to limit the number of their children by the exercise of self-restraint. He reprobated all artificial and unnatural methods of birth control as immoral, and as removing the necessary stimulus to industry; but he failed to grasp the whole truth that an increase of population is necessary as a stimulus not only to industry, but also as essential to man's moral and intellectual progress.

    (b) The Neo-Malthusians

    The Malthusian League accept the theory of their revered teacher, but, curiously enough, they reject his advice “as being impracticable and productive of the greatest possible evils to health and morality.” [3] On the contrary, they advise universal early marriage, combined with artificial birth control. Although their policy is thus in flat contradiction to the policy of Malthus, there are two things common to both. Each is based on the same fallacy, and the aim of both is wide of the mark. Indeed, the Neo-Malthusian, like Malthus, has “a mist of speculation over his facts, and a vapour of fact over his ideas.” [4] Moreover, as will be shown here, the path of the Malthusian League, although at first glance an easy way out of many human difficulties, is in reality the broad road along which a man or a nation travels to destruction; and as guides the Neo-Malthusians are utterly unsafe, since they argue from (a) false premises to (b) false deductions. We shall deal with the former in this chapter.

    Section 2. TEACHING BASED ON FALSE PREMISES

    The theory of Malthus is based on three errors, namely (a) that the population increases in geometrical progression, a progression of 1, 2, 4, 8, 16, and so on upwards; (b) that the food supply increases in arithmetical progression, a progression of 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, and so on upwards; and (c) that overpopulation is the cause of poverty and disease. If we show that de facto there is no overpopulation it obviously cannot be a cause of anything, nor be itself caused by the joint operation of the first two causes. However, each of the errors can be severally refuted.

    (a) In the first place, it is true that a population might increase in geometrical progression, and that a woman might bear thirty children in her lifetime; but it is wrong to assume that because a thing might happen, it therefore does happen. The population, as a matter of fact, does not increase in geometrical progression, because Nature [5] places her own checks on the birth-rate, and no woman bears all the children she might theoretically bear, apart altogether from artificial birth control.

    (b) Secondly, the food supply does not of necessity increase in arithmetical progression, because food is produced by human hands, and is therefore increased in proportion to the increase of workers, unless the food supply of a country or of the world has reached its limit. The food supply of the world might reach a limit beyond which it could not be increased; but as yet this event has not happened, and there is no indication whatsoever that it is likely to happen.

    Human life is immediately sustained by food, clothing, shelter, and fuel. Food and clothing are principally derived from fish, fowl, sheep, cattle, and grain, all of which tend, more so than man, to increase in geometrical ratio, although actually their increase in this progression is checked by man or by Nature. As regards shelter there can be no increase at all, either arithmetical or geometrical, apart from the work of human hands. Again, the stock of fuel in or on the earth cannot increase of itself, and is gradually becoming exhausted. On the other hand, within living memory, new sources of fuel, such as petroleum, have been made available, and old varieties of fuel have been used to better advantage, as witness the internal-combustion engine driven by smoke from sawdust. Moreover, in the ocean tides is a vast energy that one day may take the place of fuel.

    (c) Thirdly, before anyone can reasonably maintain that overpopulation is the cause of poverty and disease, it is necessary to prove that overpopulation actually exists or is likely to occur in the future. By overpopulation we mean the condition of a country in which there are so many inhabitants that the production of necessaries of livelihood is insufficient for the support of all, with the result that many people are overworked or ill-fed. Under these circumstances the population can be said to press on the soil: and unless their methods of production could be improved, or resources secured from outside, the only possible remedy against the principle of diminishing returns would be a reduction of population; otherwise, the death-rate from want and starvation would gradually rise until it equalled the birth-rate in order to maintain an unhappy equilibrium.

    Section 3. THE ROOT FALLACY

    According to Malthusian doctrine overpopulation is the cause of poverty, disease, and war: and consequently, unless the growth of population is artificially restrained, all attempts to remedy social evils are futile. Malthusians claim that “if only the devastating torrent of children could be arrested for a few years, it would bring untold relief.” They hold that overpopulation is the root of all social evil, and the truth or falsehood of that proposition is therefore the basis of all their teaching. Now, when Malthusians are asked to prove that this their basic proposition is true, they adopt one of two methods, not of proof, but of evasion. Their first method of evading the question is by asserting that the truth of their proposition is self-evident and needs no proof. To that we reply that the falsity of the proposition can and will be proved. Their second device is to put up a barrage of facts which merely show that all countries, and indeed the earth itself, would have been overpopulated long ago if the increase of population had not been limited by certain factors, ranging from celibacy and late marriages to famines, diseases, wars, and infanticide. The truth of these facts is indisputable, but it is nevertheless a manifest breach of logic to argue from the fact of poverty, disease, and war having checked an increase of population, that therefore poverty, disease, and war are due to an increase of population. It would be as reasonable to argue that, because an unlimited increase of insects is prevented by birds and by climatic changes, therefore an increase of insects accounts for the existence of birds, and for variations of climate. Nor is it of any use for Malthusians to say that overpopulation might be the cause of poverty. They cannot prove that it is the cause of poverty, and, as will be shown in the following chapter, more obvious and probable causes are staring them in the face. For our present purpose it will suffice if we are able to prove that overpopulation has not occurred in the past and is unlikely to occur in the future.

    Section 4. WHAT OVERPOPULATION MEANS

    In the first place, the meaning of the word “overpopulation” should be clearly understood. The word does not mean a very large number of inhabitants in a country. If that were its meaning the Malthusian fallacy could be disproved by merely pointing out that poverty exists both in thinly populated and in thickly populated countries. Now, in reality, overpopulation would occur whenever the production of the necessities of life in a country was insufficient for the support of all the inhabitants. For example, a barren rock in the ocean would be overpopulated, even if it contained only one inhabitant. It follows that the term “overpopulation” should be applied only to an economic situation in which the population presses on the soil. The point may be illustrated by a simple example.

    Let us assume that a fertile island of 100 acres is divided into 10 farms, each of 10 acres, and each capable of supporting a family of ten. Under these conditions the island could support a population of 1,000 people without being overpopulated. If, however, the numbers in each family increased to 20 the population would press on the soil, and the island, with 2,000 inhabitants, would be an example of overpopulation, and of poverty due to overpopulation.

    On the other hand, let us assume that there are only 1,000 people on the island, but that one family of ten individuals has managed to gain possession of eight farms, in addition to their own, and that the other nine families are forced to live on one farm. Obviously, 900 people would be attempting to live under conditions of dire poverty, and the island, with its population of 1,000, would now offer an excellent example, not of overpopulation, but of human selfishness.

    My contentions are that poverty is neither solely nor indeed generally related to economic pressure on the soil; that there are many causes of poverty apart altogether from overpopulation; and that in reality overpopulation does not exist in those countries where Malthusians claim to find proofs of social misery due to a high birthrate.

    If overpopulation in the economic sense occurred in a closed country, whose inhabitants were either unable or unwilling to send out colonies, it is obvious that general poverty and misery would result. This might happen in small islands, but it is of greater interest to know what does happen.

    Section 5. NO EVIDENCE OF OVERPOPULATION

    In a closed country, producing all its own necessities of life and incapable of expansion, a high birth-rate would eventually increase the struggle for existence and would lead to overpopulation, always provided that, firstly, the high birth-rate is accompanied by a low death-rate, and secondly, that the high birth-rate is maintained. For example, although a birth-rate was high, a population would not increase in numbers if the death-rate was equally high. Therefore, a high birth-rate does not of necessity imply that population will be increased or that overpopulation will occur. Again, if the birth-rate fell as the population increased, the danger of overpopulation would be avoided without the aid of a high death-rate. For a moment, however, let us assume that the Malthusian premise is correct, that a high birth-rate has led to overpopulation, and that the struggle for existence has therefore increased. Then obviously the death-rate would rise; the effect of the high birth-rate would be neutralised; and beyond a certain point neither the population nor the struggle for existence could be further increased. On these grounds Neo-Malthusians argue that birth-control is necessary precisely to obviate that cruel device whereby Nature strives to restore the balance upset by a reckless increase of births; and that the only alternative to frequent and premature deaths is regulation of the source of life. As a corollary to this proposition they claim that, if the death-rate be reduced, a country is bound to become overpopulated unless the births are artificially controlled. Fortunately it is possible to test the truth of this corollary, because certain definite observations on this very point have been recorded. These observations do not support the argument of birth controllers.

    (a) In the Suez Canal Zone

    In the Suez Canal Zone there was a high death-rate chiefly owing to fever. According to Malthus it would have been a great mistake to lower this death-rate, because, if social conditions were improved, the population would rapidly increase and exceed the resources of the country. Now, in fact, the social conditions were improved, the death-rate was lowered, and the subsequent events, utterly refuting the above contention, are thus noted by Dr. Halford Ross, who was medical officer in that region:

        “During the years 1901 to 1910, health measures in this zone produced a
        very considerable fall in the death-rate, from 30.2 per thousand to
        19.6 per thousand; the infant mortality was also reduced very greatly,
        and it was expected that, after a lapse of time, the reduction of the
        death-rate would result in a rise of the birth-rate, and a
        corresponding increase of the population. But such was not the case.
        When the death-rate fell, the birthrate fell too, and the number of the
        population remained the same as before, even after nearly a decade had
        passed, and notwithstanding the fact that the whole district had become
        much healthier, and one town, Port Said, was converted from an
        unhealthy, fever-stricken place into a seaside health resort.” [6]

    Moreover, Dr. Halford Ross has told me that artificial birth control was not practised in this region, and played no part in maintaining a stationary population. The majority of the people were strict Mohammedans, amongst whom the practice of birth control is forbidden by the Koran.

    (b) In “Closed Countries” like Japan

    But a much more striking example of the population in a closed country remaining stationary without the practice of birth control, thus refuting the contention of our birth controllers, is to be found in their own periodical, The Malthusian. [7] It would appear that in Japan from 1723 to 1846 the population remained almost stationary, only increasing from 26,065,422 to 26,907,625. In 1867 the Shogunate was abolished, the Emperor was restored, and Japan began to be a civilised power. Now from 1872 the population increased by 10,649,990 in twenty-seven years, and “during the period between 1897 and 1907 the population received an increment of 11.6 per cent., whereas the food-producing area increased by only 4.4 per cent.... According to Professor Morimoro, the cost of living is now so high in Japan that 98 per cent, of the people do not get enough to eat.” From these facts certain obvious deductions may be made. So long as Japan was a closed country her population remained stationary. When she became a civilised industrial power the mass of her people became poorer, the birth-rate rose, and the population increased, this last result being the real problem to-day in the Far East. In face of these facts it is sheer comedy to learn that our Malthusians are sending a woman to preach birth control amongst the Japanese! Do they really believe that for over a hundred years Japan, unlike most semi-barbaric countries, practised birth control, and that when she became civilised she refused, unlike most civilised countries, to continue this practice? There is surely a limit to human credulity.

    The truth appears to be that in closed countries the population remains more or less stationary, that Nature herself checks the birth-rate without the aid of artificial birth control, and that birthrates and death-rates are independently related to the means of subsistence.

    Section 6. A NATURAL LAW CHECKING FERTILITY

    During the past century the population of Europe increased by about 160,000,000, but it is utterly unreasonable to assume that this rate of increase will be maintained during the present century. It would be as sensible to argue that because a child is four feet high at the age of ten he will be eight feet high at the age of twenty. Moreover, there is evidence that, apart altogether from vice, the fertility of a nation is reduced at every step in civilisation. The cause of this reduction in fertility is unknown. It is probably a reaction to many complex influences, and possibly associated with the vast growth of great cities. This decline in the fertility of a community is a natural protection against the possibility of overpopulation; but, on the other hand, there is a point beyond which any further decline in fertility will bring a community within sight of depopulation and of extinction.

    Section 7. OVERPOPULATION IN THE FUTURE

    It is a fallacy to say that overpopulation is the cause of poverty and disease, and that for the simple reason that overpopulation has not yet occurred. For the growth of a nation we assume that the birth-rate should exceed the death-rate by from 10 to 20 per thousand, and it is obvious that in a closed country the evil of overpopulation might appear in a comparatively short time. The natural remedies in the past have been emigration and colonisation. According to the birth controllers these remedies are only temporary, because sooner or later all colonies and eventually the earth itself will be overpopulated. At the British Association Meeting in 1890 the population of the earth was said to be 1,500 millions, and it was calculated that only 6,000 millions could live on the earth. This means that if the birth-rate throughout the world exceeded the death-rate by only 8 per thousand, the earth would be overpopulated within 200 years. It is probable that in these calculations the capacity of the earth to sustain human life has been underestimated; that the earth could support not four times but sixteen times its present population; and that the latter figure could be still further increased by the progress of inventions. But, apart altogether from the accuracy of these figures, the danger of overpopulation is nothing more or less than a myth. Indeed, the end of the world, a philosophic and scientific certitude, is a more imminent event than its overpopulation.

    Section 8. HOW NATIONS HAVE PERISHED

    Before speculating on what might happen in the future, it is well to recollect what has happened in the past. The earth has been inhabited for thousands of years, and modern research has revealed the remains of many ancient civilisations that have perished. For example, there were the great nations of Cambodia and of Guatemala. In Crete, about 2000 B.C., there existed a civilisation where women were dressed as are this evening the women of London and Paris. That civilisation perished, and even its language cannot now be deciphered. Why did these civilisations perish? Surely this momentous question should take precedence over barren discussions as to whether there will be sufficient food on the land or in the sea for the inhabitants of the world in 200 years' time. How came it about that these ancient nations did not double their numbers every fifty years and fill up the earth long ago?

    The answer is that they were overcome and annihilated by the incidence of one or other of two dangers that threaten every civilisation, including our own. These dangers are certain physical and moral catastrophes, against which there is only one form of natural insurance, namely, a birth-rate that adequately exceeds the death-rate. They help to illustrate further the fallacy of the overpopulation scare.

    The following is a general outline of these dangers, and in a later chapter (p. 70)(see [Reference: Dangers]) I shall quote an example of how they have operated in the past.

    Section 9. PHYSICAL CATASTROPHES

    Deaths from famine, floods, earthquakes, and volcanic eruptions are confined to comparatively small areas, and the two physical catastrophes that may seriously threaten a civilisation may be reduced to endemic disease and war.

    (a) Disease

    Disease, in the form of malaria, contributed to the fall of ancient Greece and Rome. In the fourteenth century 25,000,000 people, one-quarter of the population of Europe, were exterminated by plague, the “Black Death,” and in the sixteenth century smallpox depopulated Spanish America. Although these particular diseases have lost much of their power owing to the progress of medical science, we have no right to assume that disease in general has been conquered by our civilisation, or that a new pestilence may not appear. On the contrary, in 1805, a new disease, spotted fever, appeared in Geneva, and within half a century had become endemic throughout Europe and America. Of this fever during the Great War the late Sir William Osler wrote: “In cerebro-spinal fever we may be witnessing the struggle of a new disease to win a place among the great epidemics of the world.” There was a mystery about this disease, because, although unknown in the Arctic Circle, it appeared in temperate climates during the coldest months of the year. As I was able to prove in 1915, [8] it is a disease of civilisation. I found that the causal organism was killed in thirty minutes by a temperature of 62 deg. F. It was thus obvious that infection could never be carried by cold air. But in overcrowded rooms where windows are closed, and the temperature of warm, impure, saturated air was raised by the natural heat of the body to 80 deg. F or over, the life of the microorganism, expelled from the mouths of infected people during the act of coughing, was prolonged. Infection is thus carried from one person to another by warm currents of moving air, and at the same time resistance against the disease is lowered. Cold air kills the organism, but cold weather favours the disease. In that paradox the aetiology of cerebro-spinal fever became as clear as the means of prevention. The story of spotted fever reveals the forces of nature fighting against the disease at every turn, and implacably opposed to its existence, while man alone, of his own will and folly, harbours infection and creates the only conditions under which the malady can appear. For example, during two consecutive winters cerebro-spinal fever had appeared in barracks capable of housing 2,000 men. A simple and effective method of ventilation was then introduced. From that day to this not a single case of cerebro-spinal fever has occurred in these barracks, although there have been outbreaks of this disease in the town in which the barracks are situated.

    There are many other diseases peculiar to civilisation, and concerning the wherefore and the why an apposite passage occurs in the works of Sir William Gull.

        “Causes affecting health and shortening life may be inappreciable in
        the individual, but sufficiently obvious when their effect is
        multiplied a thousandfold. If the conditions of society render us
        liable to many diseases, they in return enable us to establish the
        general laws of life and health, a knowledge of which soon becomes a
        distributive blessing. The cure of individual diseases, whilst we leave
        open the dark fountains from which they spring, is to labour like
        Sisyphus, and have our work continually returning upon our hands. And,
        again, there are diseases over which, directly, we have little or no
        control, as if Providence had set them as signs to direct us to wider
        fields of inquiry and exertion. Even partial success is often denied,
        lest we should rest satisfied with it, and forget the truer and better
        means
    of prevention.” [9]

    Medical and sanitary science have made great progress in the conquest of enteric fever, diphtheria, scarlet fever, measles, and whooping cough. The mortality from bronchitis and from pulmonary tuberculosis has also been reduced, but nevertheless tuberculosis still claims more victims in the prime of life than any other malady. It is a disease of civilisation and is intimately associated with economic conditions. The history of tuberculosis has yet to be written. On the other hand, deaths from certain other diseases are actually increasing, as witness the following figures from the Reports of the Registrar-General for England and Wales:

        Disease. Number of Number of
                         deaths in Deaths in
                         1898. 1919.

        Diseases of the heart and
        circulatory system 50,492 69,637
        Cancer 25,196 42,144
        Pneumonia 35,462 38,949
        Influenza 10,405 44,801

    In view of these figures it is folly to suppose that the final conquest of disease is imminent.

    (b) War

    War, foreign or civil, is another sword hanging over civilisations, whereby the fruits of a long period of growth may be destroyed in a few years. After the Thirty Years War the recovery of Germany occupied a century and a half. During the fourteen years of the Taiping rebellion in China whole provinces were devastated and millions upon millions of people were killed or died. In spite of the Great War during the past decade, there are some who would delude themselves and others into the vain belief that, without a radical change in international relations and a determined effort to neutralise its causes, there will be no more war; but unless the nations learn through Christianity that justice is higher than self-interest the following brilliant passage by Devas is as true to-day as when it was written in 1901:

        “True that the spread of humanitarianism and cosmopolitanism made many
        people think, towards the end of the nineteenth century, that bloodshed
        was at an end. But their hopes were dreams: the visible growth of
        national rivalry and gigantic armaments can only issue in desperate
        struggles; while not a few among the nations are troubled with the
        growth of internal dissensions and accumulations of social hatred that
        point to bloody catastrophes in the future; and the tremendous means of
        destruction that modern science puts in our hands offer frightful
        possibilities of slaughter, murderous anarchical outrages, and rivers
        of blood shed in pitiless repression.” [10]

    Malthusians may inveigh against wars waged to achieve the expansion of a nation, but so long as international rivalry disregards the moral law their words will neither stop war nor prevent a Malthusian country from falling an easy prey to a stronger people. On the contrary, a low birthrate, by reducing the potential force available for defence, is actually an incentive to a declaration of war from an envious neighbour, because it means that he will not hesitate so long when attempting to count the cost beforehand. In 1850 the population of France and Germany numbered practically the same, 35,500,000; in 1913 that of France was 39,600,000, that of Germany 67,000,000. [11] The bearing of these facts on the Great War is obvious. In 1919 the new Germany, including Silesia, had a population of just over 60,000,000; whereas, in 1921, France, including Alsace-Lorraine, had a population of 39,200,000. Thus, despite her victory in the war, the population of France is less to-day than it was seven years ago.

    Section 10. MORAL CATASTROPHES

    In view of past history only an ostrich with its head in the sand can profess to believe that there will be no calamities in the future to reduce the population of the earth. And apart from cataclysms of disease or of war, empires have perished by moral catastrophe. A disbelief in God results in selfishness, and in various moral catastrophes. In the terse phrase of Mr. Bernard Shaw, “Voluptuaries prosper and perish.” [12] For example, during the second century B.C. the disease of rationalism, [13] spread over Greece, and a rapid depopulation of the country began.

    The facts were recorded by Polybius, [14] who expressly states that at the time of which he is writing serious pestilences did not occur, and that depopulation was caused by the selfishness of the Greeks, who, being addicted to pleasure, either did not marry at all or refused to rear more than one or two children, lest it should be impossible to bring them up in extravagant luxury. This ancient historian also noted that the death of a son in war or by pestilence is a serious matter when there are only one or two sons in a family. Greece fell to the conquering Romans, and they also in course of time were infected with this evil canker. There came a day when over the battlements of Constantinople the blood-red Crescent was unfurled. Later on all Christendom was threatened, and the King of France appealed to the Pope for men and arms to resist the challenge to Europe of the Mohammedan world. The Empire of the Turk spread over the whole of South-Eastern Europe. But once more the evil poison spread, this time into the homes in many parts of Islam, and to-day the once triumphant foes of Christianity are decaying nations whose dominions are the appanage of Europe. In face of these facts it is sheer madness to assume that all the Great Powers now existing will maintain their population and prove immune from decay. Indeed, the very propaganda against which this Essay is directed is in itself positive proof that the seeds of decay have already been sown within the British Empire. Yet, in an age in which thought and reason are suppressed by systematised confusion and spiritless perplexity, the very simplicity of a truth will operate against its general acceptance.

    From the theological point of view, the myth of overpopulation is definitely of anti-Christian growth, because it assumes that, owing to the operation of natural instincts implanted in mankind by the Creator, the only alternative offered to the race is a choice between misery and vice, an alternative utterly incompatible with Divine goodness in the government of the world.

    [Footnote 1: The birth-rate is the number of births per 1,000 of the whole population. In order to make a fair comparison between one community and another, the birth-rate is often calculated as the number of births per 1,000 married women between 15 and 45 years of age, as these constitute the great majority of child-bearing mothers. This is called the corrected birth-rate.]

    [Footnote 2: Economic Review, January 1892.]

    [Footnote 3: So says the Secretary of the Malthusian League. Vide The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 88.]

    [Footnote 4: Bagehot, Economic Studies, p. 193.]

    [Footnote 5: To assign a personality to “Nature” is, of course, a mere facon de parler; the believer holds that the “course of Nature” is an expression of the Mind and Will of the Creator.]

    [Footnote 6: Problems of Population, p. 382.]

    [Footnote 7: The Malthusian, July 15, 1921.]

    [Footnote 8: Lancet, 1915, vol. ii, p. 862.]

    [Footnote 9: The New Sydenham Society, vol. clvi, section viii, p. 12.]

    [Footnote 10: Charles S. Devas, Political Economy, 1901, p. 191.]

    [Footnote 11: Revue Pratique d'Apologetique, September 15, 1914.]

    [Footnote 12: Man and Superman, p. 195.]

    [Footnote 13: By rationalism we mean a denial of God and of responsibility for conduct to a Higher Being.]

    [Footnote 14: Quoted by W.H.S. Jones, Malaria and Greek History 1909, p95.]

    CHAPTER II. THE FALSE DEDUCTIONS CONCERNING POVERTY

    From the original root-fallacy Malthus argued that poverty, prostitution, war, disease, and a high death-rate are necessary in order to keep down the population: and from the same false premises birth controllers are now arguing that a high birth-rate causes (1) poverty, and (2) a high death-rate. The steps in the argument whereby these amazing conclusions are reached are as follows. Before the death-rate can be lowered the social conditions of the people must be improved; if social conditions are improved there will be an enormous increase of population in geometrical progression; the food supply of the country and even of the world cannot be increased at the same rate; and therefore there will be greater poverty and a higher death-rate unless the birth-rate is lowered. Thus Malthusians argue. In view of the false premises on which their argument is based, it is not surprising to find that their deductions are erroneous and contain many economic and statistical fallacies, to the consideration of which we may now devote our attention.

    Section 1. BIRTH-RATE AND POVERTY

    The first false deduction of birth controllers is that a high birth-rate, by intensifying the struggle for existence, increases poverty. In order to bolster up this contention, Malthusians quote three arguments concerning (a) famines, (b) abundance, and (c) wages, and each of these arguments is fallacious.

    (a) Famines

    The prevalence of famines is quoted as a proof of reckless overpopulation. Now a famine may occur from several different causes, some within and others beyond the control of man, but a failure of crops has never yet been caused by pressure on the soil. On the contrary, famine is less likely to arise in a country whose soil is intensively cultivated, because intensive cultivation means a variety of crops, and therefore less risk of all the crops failing. Moreover, during the past century famine has occurred in Bengal, where population is dense; in Ireland, where population is moderate, and in Eastern Russia, where population is scanty. The existence of famine is therefore no proof that a country is overpopulated, although it may indicate that a country is badly governed or under-developed.

    (b) Abundance

    Malthusians also claim that by means of artificial birth control we could live in a land of abundance. They point out that, as the population of a new colony increases, the colonists, by applying the methods of civilisation to the rich soil, become more and more prosperous. Eventually there comes a time when capital or labour applied to the soil gives a maximum return per head of population. Once that point has been reached any further capital or labour applied to the soil will produce a smaller return per head of population. This “law of diminishing returns” may be illustrated by a simpler example. Let us suppose that during one year a market garden worked by one man has produced vegetables to the value of L10. During the second year the garden is worked by ten men and produces vegetables to the value of L200. It is obvious that the work of ten men has produced twice as much per head as the work of one man, because each man has produced not L10 but L20. During the third year the garden is worked by twenty men and yields vegetables to the value of L300. The total yield is greater, but the yield per head is less, because each man has produced not L20 but L15. The point of maximum production per head has been passed, and the law of diminishing returns is operating.

    By restricting the birth-rate Malthusians would limit the population to the number necessary for maximum production per head. Now, in the first place, it would be very difficult, if not impossible, in the case of a country with various industries, to decide when the line of maximum production had been passed at any given time. Moreover, it would be utterly impossible to fix this line permanently. In the case of our market garden the introduction of intensive horticulture might mean that maximum production per head required the work of forty men. Again, the very phrase “maximum production per head” implies sterling moral qualities in the workers, and an absence of drones; and sterling moral qualities have never been prominent in any nation, once the practice of artificial birth control has been adopted. Lastly, the Christian ideal requires for its realisation, not a maximum, but an adequate supply of food, clothing, shelter, and fuel. Christianity teaches that to seek after the maximum enjoyment of material things is not the chief end of man, because the life of a man in this world is very short compared with his life in eternity.

    (c) Wages

    The Wages Fund Theory is an economic reflection of the Malthusian myth. This theory assumes that a definite fixed sum is available every year for distribution as wages amongst labourers, so that the more numerous the labourers the less wages will each one receive. From this theory Malthusians argue that the only remedy for low wages is artificial birth control. They carefully refrain from telling the working classes the other aspect of this Wages Fund theory—namely, that if the workers in one trade receive a rise in wages, a corresponding reduction must be made in the wages of others, so that a rise in wages here and there confers no real benefit on the labouring classes as a whole. That is merely one illustration of capitalist bias in the Malthusian propaganda. In any case, economic science has discarded the Wages Fund Theory as a pure fiction. No fixed or definite sum is available for wages, because the wages of a labourer are derived from the produce of his work. Even in the case of making a railway, where wages are paid before the work is completed, the money is advanced by shareholders on the security of the proceeds that will eventually accrue from the produce of the labourers.

    Section 2. POVERTY IN GREAT BRITAIN DUE TO OTHER CAUSES

    (a) Under-development

    Even if the theory of birth controllers, that a high birth-rate increases poverty, were as true as it is false, it could not possibly apply to Great Britain or to any other country open to commercial intercourse with the world; because there is no evidence that the supply of food in the world either cannot or will not be increased to meet any actual or possible demand. Within the British Empire alone there was an increase of 75 per cent. in the production of wheat between 1901 and 1911. [15] In Great Britain there has been not only an increase of population but also an increased consumption of various foods per head of the population. Moreover, if Britain were as well cultivated as is Flanders we could produce all or nearly all our own food. [16]

    The truth is that in countries such as England, Belgium, and Bengal, usually cited by Malthusians, as illustrating the misery that results from overpopulation, there is no evidence whatsoever to prove that the population is pressing on the soil. On the contrary, we find ample physical resources sufficient to support the entire population, and we also find evidence of human injustice, incapacity, and corruption sufficient to account for the poverty and misery that exist in these countries. This was especially so in Ireland during the first half of the nineteenth century. [17] Moreover, so far from high birth-rates being the cause of poverty, we shall find that poverty is one of the causes of a high birth-rate (p. 69).

    (b) Severance of the Inhabitants from the Soil

    It was not a high birth-rate that established organised poverty in England. In the sixteenth century the greater part of the land, including common land belonging to the poor, was seized by the rich. They began by robbing the Catholic Church, and they ended by robbing the people. [18] Once machinery was introduced in the eighteenth century, the total wealth of England was enormously increased; but the vast majority of the people had little share in this increase of wealth that accrued from machinery, because only a small portion of the people possessed capital. More children came, but they came to conditions of poverty and of child-labour in the mills. In countries where more natural and stable social conditions exist, and where there are many small owners of land, large families, so far from being a cause of poverty, are of the greatest assistance to their parents and to themselves. There are means whereby poverty could be reduced, but artificial birth control would only increase the total poverty of the State, and therefore of the individual.

    From early down to Tudor times, the majority of the inhabitants of England lived on small holdings. For example, in the fifteenth century there were twenty-one small holdings on a particular area measuring 160 acres. During the sixteenth century the number of holdings on this area had fallen to six, and in the seventeenth century the 160 acres became one farm. Occasionally an effort was made to check this process, and by a statute of Elizabeth penalties were enacted against building any cottages “without laying four acres of land thereto.” On the other hand, acres upon acres were given to the larger landowners by a series of Acts for the enclosure of common land, whereby many labourers were deprived of their land. From the reign of George I to that of George III nearly four thousand enclosure bills were passed. These wrongs have not been righted.

        “To urge,” wrote Professor Bain, “that there is sufficient poverty and
        toil in the world without bringing in more to share it than can be
        provided for, implies either begging the question at issue—a direct
        imputation that the world is at present very badly managed—or that all
        persons should take it upon themselves to say how much poverty and toil
        will exist in any part of the world in the future, or limit the
        productiveness of any race, because inadequate means of feeding,
        clothing, or employing them may be adopted in that part of time
        sometimes called unborn eternity. As a rule, the result usually has
        been: limit the increase of population without adequate cause, and the
        reaction causes deterioration or annihilation.” [19]

    Lastly, there is evidence that poverty has existed in thinly populated countries. Richard Cobden, writing in 1836, of Russia, states: “The mass of the people are sunk in poverty, ignorance, and barbarism, scarcely rising above a state of nature, and yet it has been estimated that this country contains more than 750,000 square miles of land, of a quality not inferior to the best portions of Germany, and upon which a population of 200,000,000 might find subsistence.” [20]

    Section 3. CAUSES OF POVERTY IN INDIA

    In reality chronic poverty exists both in the thickly-peopled and in the thinly-peopled regions of India, and therefore the overpopulation theory is an inadequate explanation. Moreover, there are certain obvious and admitted evils, sufficient in themselves to account for the chronic poverty of India, and of these four are quoted by Devas. [21]

        “(1) The grave discouragement to all rural improvement and in
        particular to the sinking of deep wells, by the absence outside Bengal
        of fixity of tenure, the landholder having the prospect of his
        assessment being raised every fifteen or thirty years. (2) Through most
        of India the unchecked oppression of usurers, in whose toils many
        millions of landholders are so bound as to lack means or motive for the
        proper cultivation of the soil. (3) A system of law and police totally
        unfit for small cultivators—witness the plague of litigation, appeals
        as 250 to 1 in England, habitual perjury, manufactured crime, and
        blackmailing by corrupt native police, all destructive of rural amity,
        co-operation, and industry. (4) Taxation oppressive both in quantity
        and quality: demanded, on pain of eviction and imprisonment, to be paid
        punctually and rigidly in cash, instead of optionally or occasionally
        in kind, or flexible, according to the variations of the seasons;
        moreover, levied on salt, raising the price of this necessity of life
        at least ten times, often much more; when precisely an abundant supply
        of salt, with the climate and diet of India, is a prime need for men
        and cattle.”

    Section 4. POVERTY IN FACT CAUSES A HIGH BIRTH-RATE

    As will be shown in Chapter V, poverty is generally the cause and not the result of a high birth-rate. The Malthusian doctrine has been and is to-day a barrier to social reform, because it implies that humane legislation, by encouraging population, will of necessity defeat the aim of those who desire to improve the conditions of the poor by methods other than the practice of artificial birth control. To a very great extent Malthusian teaching was responsible for the Poor Law of 1834, the most severe in Europe, the demoralising laxity of the old Poor Law being replaced by degrading severity. Again, as recently as 1899, a Secretary of State reiterated the Malthusian doctrine by explaining that great poverty throughout India was due to the increase of population under the pax Britannica. Now the truth is that if the social conditions of the poor were improved, we have every reason to believe that their birth-rate would be reduced, because as civilisation in a community progresses there is a natural decline in fertility. Hence:

    (a) Malthusianism is an Attack on the Poor

    Both the supporters and the opponents of Malthus are often mistaken in considering his greatest achievement to be a policy of birth control. Malthus did a greater and a more evil thing. He forged a law of nature, namely, that there is always a limited and insufficient supply of the necessities of life in the world. From this false law he argued that, as population increases too rapidly, the newcomers cannot hope to find a sufficiency of good things; that the poverty of the masses is not due to conditions created by man, but to a natural law; and that consequently this law cannot be altered by any change in political institutions. This new doctrine was eagerly adopted by the rich, who were thus enabled to argue that Nature intended that the masses should find no room at her feast; and that therefore our system of industrial capitalism was in harmony with the Will of God. Most comforting dogma! Most excellent anodyne for conscience against acceptance of those rights of man that, being ignored, found terrible expression in the French Revolution! Without discussion, without investigation, and without proof, our professors, politicians, leader-writers, and even our well-meaning socialists, have accepted as true the bare falsehood that there is always an insufficient supply of the necessities of life; and to-day this heresy permeates all our practical politics. In giving this forged law of nature to the rich, Malthus robbed the poor of hope. Such was his crime against humanity. In the words of Thorold Rogers, Malthusianism was part and parcel of “a conspiracy, conceived by the law and carried out by parties interested in its success, to cheat the English workman of his wages, to tie him to the soil, to deprive him of hope, and to degrade him into immediate poverty.” When Malthusians enter a slum for the purpose of preaching birth control, it is right that the people should be told what is written on the passports of these strangers.

    (b) A Hindrance to Reform

    The teaching of birth control amongst the poor is in itself a crime, because, apart from the evil practice, the people are asked to believe a lie, namely, that a high birth-rate is the cause of poverty and that by means of birth-control their circumstances will be improved. By one advocate of birth control this weak reasoning and inconsequential sentimentality have actually been crowded into the compass of a single sentence: “We must no longer be content to remain indifferent and idle witnesses of the senseless and unthinking procreating of countless wretched children, whose parents are diseased and vicious.” [22] It is true that disease, vice, and wretched children are the saddest products of our industrial system; it is also true that a helpless baby never yet was guilty of expropriating land, of building slums, of under-paying the workers, or of rigging the market. Therefore instead of preventing the birth of children we should set about to rectify the evil conditions which make the lives of children and adults unhappy. Like many other policies advocated on behalf of the poor, birth control is immoral if only on this account, that it distracts attention from the real causes of poverty. In Spain birth control is not practised. I do not say there is no poverty in that country, but there is no poverty that resembles the hopeless grinding poverty of the English poor. For that strange disease, artificial birth control is a worthless remedy; and it were far better that we should turn our attention to the simple words of Cardinal Manning: “There is a natural and divine law, anterior and superior to all human and civil law, by which men have the right to live of the fruits of the soil on which they are born, and in which they are buried.” [23]

    (c) A Quack Remedy for Poverty

    Artificial birth control is one of the many quack remedies advertised for the cure of poverty, and G.K. Chesterton has given the final answer to the Malthusian assertion that some form of birth control is essential because houses are scarce:

        “Consider that simple sentence, and you will see what is the matter
        with the modern mind. I do not mean the growth of immorality; I mean
        the genesis of gibbering idiocy. There are ten little boys whom you
        wish to provide with ten top-hats; and you find there are only eight
        top-hats. To a simple mind it would seem not impossible to make two
        more hats; to find out whose business it is to make hats, and induce
        him to make hats; to agitate against an absurd delay in delivering
        hats; to punish anybody who has promised hats and failed to provide
        hats. The modern mind is that which says that if we only cut off the
        heads of two of the little boys, they will not want hats; and then the
        hats will exactly go round. The suggestion that heads are rather more
        important than hats is dismissed as a piece of mystical metaphysics.
        The assertion that hats were made for heads, and not heads for hats
        savours of antiquated dogma. The musty text which says that the body is
        more than raiment; the popular prejudice which would prefer the lives
        of boys to the mathematical arrangement of hats,—all these things are
        alike to be ignored. The logic of enlightenment is merciless; and we
        duly summon the headsman to disguise the deficiencies of the hatter.
        For it makes very little difference to the logic of the thing, that we
        are talking of houses and not of hats.... The fundamental fallacy
        remains the same; that we are beginning at the wrong end, because we
        have never troubled to consider at what end to begin.” [24]

    Section 5. POVERTY AND CIVILISATION

    A modern writer is burdened by many words that carry an erroneous meaning, and one of these is the word “civilisation.” Intended to mean “The Art of Living,” this word, by wrong usage, now implies that our method of combining mental culture and bodily comfort is the highest, noblest, and best way to live. Yet this implication is by no means certain. On the contrary, the spectacle of our social life would bring tears to eyes undimmed by the industrial traditions of the past hundred years. This I know to be true, having once travelled to London in the company of a young girl who came from the Thirteenth Century. She had lived some twelve years on the Low Sierra of Andalusia, where in a small sunlit village she may have vainly imagined our capital to be a city with walls of amethyst and streets of gold, for when the train passed through that district which lies to the south of Waterloo, the child wept. “Look at these houses,” she sobbed; “Dios mio, they have no view.”

    [Footnote 15: Memorandum issued by the Dominions Royal Commission, December 3, 1915 (p. 2).]

    [Footnote 16: Prince Kropotkin, Fields, Factories, and Workshops, 1899, chapter iii.]

    [Footnote 17: Vide The Economic History of Ireland from the Union to the Famine, by S. O'Brien (Longmans, 1921).]

    [Footnote 18: William Cobbett, Social Effects of the Reformation. Catholic Truth Society (H. 132), price 2_d.]

    [Footnote 19: Quoted by F.P. Atkinson, M.D., in Edinburgh Medical Journal, September 1880, p. 229.]

    [Footnote 20: Ibid., p. 234.]

    [Footnote 21: Charles S. Devas, Political Economy, 1901, p. 199.]

    [Footnote 22: British Medical Journal, July 23, 1921, p. 131.]

    [Footnote 23: Quoted in Tablet, November 5, 1921, p. 598.]

    [Footnote 24: Quoted from America, October 29, 1921, p. 31.]

    CHAPTER III. HIGH BIRTH-RATES NOT THE CAUSE OF HIGH DEATH-RATES

    Section 1. POVERTY AS NOW EXISTING

    The second contention of birth controllers is that a high birth-rate, by increasing poverty, causes a high death-rate. In the first place, there is no doubt that poverty, necessary features of which are mal-nutrition or insufficient food and bad housing, is directly associated with a high death-rate, although this view was once shown by the Lancet to need important qualifications.

        “With respect to the greater mortality amongst the poor than the rich,
        we have yet to learn that the only hope of lessening the death-rate
        lies in diminishing the birth-rate. We have no proof as yet that the
        majority of the evils at present surrounding the poor are necessarily
        attendant upon poverty. We have yet to see a poor population living in
        dry, well-drained, well-ventilated houses, properly supplied with pure
        water and the means of disposal of refuse. And we have yet to become
        acquainted with a poor population spending their scant earnings
        entirely, or in a very large proportion, upon the necessities of life;
        for such is not the case when half the earnings of a family are thrown
        away to provide adulterated alcoholic drinks for one member of it.
        Until reforms such as these and others have been carried out, and the
        poor are able and willing to conform to known physiological laws, it is
        premature to speak of taking measures to lessen the birth-rate—a
        proposal, be it said, which makes the humiliating confession of man's
        defeat in the battle of life.” [25]

    It will be seen that the qualifications practically remove the question from dispute. [26] If the conditions of the poor were thus altered, poverty, as it exists to-day, would of course disappear. As things are, we find that a high death-rate is related to poverty, as is proved, for example, by the death-rate from tuberculosis being four times greater in slums than in the best residential quarters of a city.

    The correct answer to the birth controllers is that a high birth-rate is not the cause of a high death-rate, because high birth-rates, as shown in the previous chapter, are not the cause of poverty, but vice versa. Moreover, all the statistical evidence goes to prove that in this matter we are right and that Malthusians are wrong.

    Section 2. HIGH BIRTH-RATE NOT THE CAUSE OF HIGH DEATH-RATE: PROVED FROM STATISTICS

    In China, where there is said to be a birth-rate of over 50 per 1,000, and where over 70 per cent. of infants are helped to die, the high death-rate is due clearly to degraded social customs. In the slums of Great Britain the high death-rate is also due to degraded social conditions. It is not due to the birth-rate. Of this the proof is simple, (a) Among the French Canadians, where the average family numbers about nine, this high birth-rate is not associated with a high death-rate, but with the increase of a thrifty, hard-working race. In Ontario the birth-rate went up from 21.10 in 1910 to 24.7 in 1911, and the death-rate fell from 14 to 12.6. (b) Again, in 1911 the corrected birth-rate for Connaught was 45.3 as against a crude rate of 24.7 for England and Wales; and in Connaught, where there is no need for Societies for preventing Parents being Cruel to their Children, the infant mortality rate [27] is very much lower than in England, although the birth-rate is much higher and the poverty much greater. In Bradford, a prosperous English town which pays particular attention to its mothers and children, the infant mortality in 1917 was 132 per 1,000 and the birth-rate 13.2. In Connaught, where there are no maternity centres or other aids to survival, but on the contrary a great dearth of the means of well-being, the infant mortality was only 50, whilst the birth-rate was actually 45! [28] So untrue is it to say that a high death-rate is due to a high birth-rate.

    Section 3. A LOW BIRTH-RATE NO GUARANTEE OF A LOW DEATH-RATE

    Again, birth controllers claim that a low birthrate leads to a low infant mortality rate. Now, it is really a very extraordinary thing that, whatever be the statement made by a Malthusian on the subject of birth-control, the very opposite is found to be the truth. During the last quarter of last century a falling birth-rate in England was actually accompanied by a rising infant mortality rate! During 1918 in Ireland [29] the crude birthrate was 19.9, with an infant mortality rate of 86, whereas in England and Wales [30] the crude birthrate was 17.7 with an infant mortality rate of 97, and in the northern boroughs the appalling rate of 120. In England and Wales the lowest infant mortality rate was found to be in the southern rural districts, where the rate was 63, but in Connaught the rate was 50.5. This means that in England a low birth-rate is associated with a high infant mortality rate, whereas in Ireland a high birth-rate is associated with a low infant mortality rate. [31] These cold figures prove that in this matter at least the poorest Irish peasants are richer than the people of England.

    Section 4. VITAL STATISTICS OF FRANCE

    The Malthusian claim that a low birth-rate leads to a low death-rate is also disproved by the vital statistics of France.

        “The death-rate of France has not declined at the same rate as the
        birth-rate has, and, while the incidence of mortality in France was
        equal to that of England in the middle of the seventies, the English
        mortality is now only five-sevenths of the French. England thus
        maintains a fair natural increase, although the birth-rate has declined
        at an even faster pace than has been the case in France....

        “The French death-rate is higher than is the case with most of her
        neighbours, and it can quite well be reduced. The reasons for her
        fairly high mortality are not to be found in climatic conditions,
        racial characteristics, or other unchangeable elements of nature, nor
        even in her occupations, since some of the most industrial regions have
        a low mortality.” [32]

    I have tabulated certain vital statistics of twenty Departments of France.

    The following table, covering two periods of five years in twenty Departments, proves that the death-rate was lower in the ten Departments having the highest birth-rate in France than in the ten Departments having the lowest birth-rate.

    TABLE I

         THE TEN DEPARTMENTS HAVING THE HIGHEST BIRTH-RATE FRANCE
                         1909-1913 1915-1919
                    Rates per 1,000 population Still- Rates per 1,000
                         births population Departments. Living Deaths Natural per 1000 Births deaths
                    births increase births

    Moselle 27.6 16.5 +11.1—14.7 15.4 Finistere 27.2 18.1 +9.1 4.0 15.9 18.2 Pas-de-Calais 26.8 17.4 +9.4 4.2—- Morbihan 25.7 17.8 +7.9 4.4 15.0 19.0 Cotes-du-Nord 24.5 20.6 +3.9 4.2 14.4 20.0 Bas-Rhin. 24.3 16.2 +8.0—13.3 16.1 Meurthe-et- Moselle 23.2 19.2 +4.0 4.3—- Lozere 22.6 17.3 +5.2 4.2 12.4 17.5 Haut-Rhin. 22.4 16.0 +6.4—10.3 15.4 Vosges 22.0 18.7 +3.3 4.7—-

    Total Averages 24.6 17.7 +6.8 4.2 13.7 17.3

         THE TEN DEPARTMENTS HAVING THE LOWEST BIRTH-RATE IN FRANCE

    Cote-d'Or. 15.4 18.2—2.8 3.1 9.9 20.5 Allier. 15.1 15.7—0.6 3.3 8.4 18.8 Gironde 15.1 17.3—2.2 4.5 10.1 21.2 Haute-Garonne. 15.1 20.4 —5.3 4.0 9.0 22.5 Lot 15.0 21.0—6.0 4.5 7.5 20.6 Nievre 14.9 17.4—2.5 3.2 8.8 20.0 Tarn-et-Garonne 14.9 20.1—5.1 4.7 7.9 20.7 Yonne 14.4 19.1—4.7 3.8 8.9 22.0 Lot-et-Garonne 13.7 19.1—5.4 4.4 7.4 20.1 Gers 13.2 19.2—6.0 4.1 6.8 19.8

    Total Averages 14.6 18.7—4.0 3.9 8.4 20.6

    Moreover, the figures show that, prior to 1914, the Departments with the lowest birth-rate were becoming depopulated. On the other hand, the enormous fall in the birth-rate throughout the country from 1915 to 1919 is a memorial, very noble, to the heroism of France in the Great War, and to her 1,175,000 dead. Certain other facts should also be noted. In France the regulations permit that, when a child has died before registration of the birth, this may be recorded as a still-birth; and for that reason the proportion of still-births appears higher than in most other countries.

    Malthusian claims are thus refuted by the vital statistics of France; but it should be clearly understood that these figures do not prove that the reverse of the Malthusian theory is true, namely, that a high birth-rate is the cause of a low death-rate. There is no true correlation between birthrates and death-rates.

    Section 5. COEFFICIENTS OF CORRELATION

    As birth controllers rely very much upon statistics, and as figures may very easily mislead the unwary, it is necessary to point out that the Malthusian contention that a high birth-rate is the cause of a high death-rate is not only contrary to reason and to facts, but is also contrary to the very figures which they quote. A high birth-rate is often associated with a high death-rate, but a general or uniform correspondence between birth-rates and death-rates has never been established by modern statistical methods. To these methods brief reference may be made. A coefficient of correlation is a number intended to indicate the degree of similarity between two things, or the extent to which one moves with the other. If this coefficient is unity, or 1, it indicates that the two things are similar in all respects, while if it be zero, or 0, it indicates that there is no resemblance between them. The study of correlation is a first step to the study of causation, because, until we know to what extent two things move together, it is useless to consider whether one causes the movement of the other; but in itself a coefficient of correlation does not necessarily indicate cause or result. Now in this country, between 1838 and 1912 the birth-rate and the death-rate show a correlation of .84; but if that period be split into two, the correlation from 1838 to 1876, when the birth-rate was fluctuating, is minus .12, and in the period after 1876 the correlation is plus .92. This means that the whole of the positive correlation is due to the falling of the death-rate, and that birthrates and death-rates do not of necessity move together. [33]

    After a careful examination of the vital statistics for France, Knud Stouman concludes as follows:

        “In France no clear correlation exists between the birth-rate and the
        death-rate in the various Departments. The coefficient of correlation
        between the birth-rate and the general death-rate by Departments
        (1909-1913) was 0.0692+-0.1067, and including Alsace and
        Lorraine—0.0212+-0.1054, indicating no correlation whatsoever. A
        somewhat different and more interesting table is obtained when the
        correlation is made with the mortality at each age class:

        TABLE II

        Under 1 year 0.3647 +-0.0986
        1-19 years 0.4884 +-0.0816
        20-39 years 0.6228 +-0.0656
        40-59 years 0.5028 +-0.0801
        60 years and over 0.2577 +-0.1001

        “A peculiar configuration is observed in these coefficients in that a
        quite pronounced positive correlation exists at the central age
        group, but disappears with some regularity towards both extremities
        of life. If the mortality has any influence upon the natality this
        cannot be in the form of replacement of lost infants and deceased old
        people, therefore, as has frequently been suggested. That a high
        death-rate at the child-bearing age should be conducive to increased
        fertility is absurd, neither does it seem likely that a large number
        of children should make the parents more liable to diseases which are
        prevalent at this period of life. The reasons must, then, be looked
        for in a common factor.

        “Now the only disease of importance representing the same age-curve as
        do the correlation coefficients is tuberculosis. This disease causes in
        France 2 per cent. of the deaths under one year, 24 per cent. of the
        deaths from 1 to 19 years of age, not less than 45 per cent. from 20 to
        39, 18 per cent. at ages 40 to 59, and less than 2 per cent. at the
        ages over 60. Will a high tuberculosis mortality, then, be conducive to
        great fertility, or do we have to fear that a decrease of the natality
        will be the result of energetic measures against tuberculosis? Hardly.
        The death-rate may be reduced, then, without detrimental effects upon
        the birth-rate.

        “What can the factor be which influences both the tuberculosis
        incidence and the birth-rate? We know that the prevalence of
        tuberculosis is conditioned principally by poverty and ignorance of
        hygiene. The Parisian statistics, as compiled by Dr. Bertillon and
        recently by Professor L. Hersch, show a much higher birth-rate in the
        poor wards than in the richer districts, and the high birth-rates may
        be furnished largely by the poorer elements of the population. A
        comfortable degree of wealth does not imply a low birth-rate, as is
        abundantly shown elsewhere, and one of the important questions which
        suggest themselves to the French statistician and sociologist is
        evidently the following: How can the intellectual and economic standard
        of the masses be raised without detriment to the natality?

        “We believe that the time is opportune for solving this question. The
        past half-century has been lived under the shadow of defeat and with a
        sense of limitations, and of impotence against fate. This nightmare is
        now thrown off, and, the doors to the world being open and development
        free, the French people will learn that new initiative has its full
        recompense and that a living and a useful activity can be found for all
        the sons and daughters they may get. The habit of home-staying is
        broken by the war, and new and great undertakings are developing in the
        ruined north-east as well as in the sunny south.” [34]

    [Footnote 25: The Lancet, 1879, vol. ii, p. 703.]

    [Footnote 26: Poverty is a term of wide import admitting many degrees according as the victim is deprived more or less completely of the ordinary necessities in the matters of food, clothing, housing, education, and recreation. As used by Malthusians and spoken of here it means persistent lack of one or more of these necessary requisites for decent living. Vide Parkinson, Primer of Social Science (1918), pp. 225 sqq.]

    [Footnote 27: The infant mortality rate is the number of deaths of infants under one year old per 1,000 births in the same year.]

    [Footnote 28: See Saleeby, The Factors of Infant Mortality, edited by Cory Bigger. Report on the Physical Welfare of Mothers and Children, vol. iv, Ireland (Carnegie U.K. Trust), 1918.]

    [Footnote 29: Fifty-fifth Annual Report of the Registrar-General for Ireland, containing a General Abstract of the Numbers of Marriages, Births, and Deaths, 1918, pp. x, xxix, and 24.]

    [Footnote 30: Eighty-first Annual Report of the Registrar-General of Births, Deaths, and Marriages in England and Wales, 1918, pp. xxiv, xxxii, and xxxv.]

    [Footnote 31: This is also the emphatic testimony of Sir Arthur Newsholme, in his Report of Child Mortality, issued in connection with the Forty-fifth Annual Report of the Local Government Board (dated 191?), PP. 77-8.]

    [Footnote 32: Knud Stouman, “The Repopulation of France,” International Journal of Public Health, vol. ii, no. 4, p. 421.]

    [Footnote 33: Dr. Major Greenwood. Vide The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 130.]

    [Footnote 34: International Journal of Public Health, vol. ii, no. 4, p. 423.]

    CHAPTER IV. HOW RELIGION AFFECTS THE BIRTHRATE

    Section 1. FRENCH STATISTICS MISINTERPRETED BY MALTHUSIANS

    The fact that Malthusians are in the habit of citing the birth-rate in certain Catholic countries as a point in favour of their propaganda is only another instance of their maladroit use of figures: because for that argument there is not the slightest justification. The following paragraph from a recent speech [35] in the Anglican Church Congress by Lord Dawson, Physician to the King, is a good example of their methods in controversy:

        “Despite the influence and condemnations of the Church, it (artificial
        birth control) has been practised in France for well over half a
        century, and in Belgium and other Catholic countries is extending. And
        if the Roman Catholic Church, with its compact organisation, its power
        of authority, and its discipline, cannot check this procedure, is it
        likely that Protestant Churches will be able to do so? For Protestant
        religions depend for their strength on the conviction and esteem they
        establish in the heads and hearts of their people
    .”

    I have italicised the closing words because it would be interesting to know, in passing, whether anyone denies that these human influences also contribute to the strength of the Catholic Church. Among recent converts to the Faith in this country are many Protestant clergymen who may be presumed to have known what claims “on their conviction and esteem” their communion had. Moreover, in France, amongst recent converts are some of the great intellects of that country. If it be not “conviction and esteem” in their “heads and hearts,” what other motive, I ask, has induced Huysmans, Barres, and others to make submission to Rome?

    Secondly, it is true that for over half a century the birth-rate of France has been falling, and that to some extent this decline is due to the use of contraceptives; but it is also true that during the past fifty years the Government of France has made a determined but unsuccessful effort to overthrow the Catholic Church; and that it is in so far as the Government has weakened Catholic influence and impeded Catholic teaching that the birth-rate has fallen. The belief of a nation will not influence its destiny unless that belief is reflected in the actions of the citizens. Father Herbert Thurston, S.J., [36] thus deals with the argument implied:

        “Catholicism which is merely Catholicism in name, and which amounts to
        no more in the supposed believer than a vague purpose of sending for a
        priest when he is dying, is not likely to have any restraining effect
        upon the decline of the birth-rate. Further, it is precisely because a
        really practical Catholicism lays such restrictions upon freedom in
        this and in other matters, that members of the educated and comfortable
        classes, the men especially, are prone to emancipate themselves from
        all religious control with an anti-clerical rancour hardly known in
        Protestant lands. Had it not been for these defections from her
        teaching, the Catholic Church, in most countries of mixed religion,
        would soon become predominant by the mere force of natural fertility.
        Even as it is, we believe that a country like France owes such small
        measure of natural increase as she still retains almost entirely to the
        religious principle of the faithful few. Where the Catholic Church
        preserves her sway over the hearts of men the maintenance of a vigorous
        stock is assured.”

    In the first place, it is noteworthy that the birth-rate varies with practical Catholicism in France, being much higher in those Departments where the Church is more flourishing. As was shown by Professor Meyrick Booth in 1914, there are certain districts of France where the birth-rate is higher than in the usual English country districts. For example, the birth-rate in Finistere was 27.1, in Pas-de-Calais 26.6, and in Morbihan 25.8. On the other hand, in many Departments the birth-rate was lower than the death-rate. This occurred, for example, in Lot, Haute Garonne, Tarn-et-Garonne, Lot-et-Garonne, and in Gers. In the two last-named Departments the birth-rates were 13.6 and 13.0 respectively.

    In the following table I have tabulated more recent figures concerning the vital statistics in these two groups of Departments, and rates for the two periods of five years, 1909-1913, and 1915-1919, in each group are compared.

    It will be noted that in the three Departments, where practical Catholicism is most flourishing,

    TABLE III

                         1909-1913. 1915-1919.

    Departments. Rates per 1000 Still-Deaths Rates per 1000
                         population Births under population
                         per 1 year
                      Living Deaths National 1000 per Births Deaths
                      Births Increase Births 1000
                         living
                         births

    Finistere. 27.2 18.1 +9.1 4.0 116.7 15.9 18.2 Pas-de-Calais 26.8 17.4 +9.4 4.2 135.3 — — Morbihan. 25.7 17.8 +7.9 4.4 113.7 15.0 19.0

    Total Averages. 26.5 17.7 +8.8 4.2 121.9 15.4 18.6

    Lot. 15.0 21.0—6.0 4.5 148.0 7.5 20.6 Haute Garonne. 15.1 20.4—5.3 4.0 121.3 9.0 22.5 Tarn-et-Garonne 14.9 20.1—5.1 4.7 134.7 7.9 20.7 Lot-et-Garonne. 13.7 19.1—5.4 4.4 112.0 7.4 20.1 Gers. 13.2 19.2—6.0 4.1 102.4 6.8 19.8

    Total Averages. 14.3 19.9—5.5 4.3 123.6 7.7 20.7

    there is a high birth-rate, and moreover that in these Departments both the death-rate and the infant mortality rate is lower than in the five Departments with the lowest birth-rate.

    Professor Meyrick Booth's comments are as follows:

        “The above five departments (in which the decline of population has
        been most marked) are adjacent to one another in the fertile valley of
        the Garonne, one of the wealthiest parts of France; and we may well
        ask: Why should the birth-rate under such favourable conditions be less
        than half that which is noted for the bleak district of Finistere? The
        noted statistician, M. Leroy-Beaulieu, has some interesting
        observations to offer upon this paradoxical state of things.
        Considering the country in general, and these districts in particular,
        he notes that the most prolific parts of France are those in which the
        people have retained their allegiance to the traditional Church (in the
        case of the Pas-de-Calais we have a certain degree of adherence to the
        orthodox faith combined with the presence of a large mining
        population). M. Leroy-Beaulieu expresses the opinion that the Catholic
        Church tends, by means of its whole atmosphere, to promote a general
        increase of population; for, more than other types of Christianity, it
        condemns egoism, materialism, and inordinate ambition for self or
        family; and, moreover, it works in the same direction through its
        uncompromising condemnation of modern Malthusian practices. He draws
        our attention, further, to the new wave of religious life which has
        swept over the haute-bourgeoisie of France during the last few
        decades; and he does not hesitate to connect this with the fact that
        this class is now one of the most prolific (perhaps the most prolific)
        in the nation. Space forbids my taking up this subject in detail, but
        it appears from a considerable body of figures which have been
        collected that, while the average number of children born to each
        marriage in the English Protestant upper middle class is not more than
        about 2.0 to 2.5, the number born to each marriage in the corresponding
        class in France is between 3.0 and 4.0. Taking the foregoing facts into
        consideration, it would appear that Roman Catholicism—even in
        France—is very considerably more prolific (where the belief of the
        people is at all deep) than English Protestantism. This applies both to
        the upper and lower classes.” [37]

    In all probability Lord Dawson was unaware of the foregoing, but there is one fact which, as a Neo-Malthusian, he ought to have known, because the omission of this fact in his address is a serious matter. When referring to France as a country where birth control had come to stay, Lord Dawson did not tell his audience that the Government of France has now suppressed the only Malthusian periodical in that country, and has proposed a law, whereby those who engage in birth control propaganda shall be imprisoned.

    Section 2. EVIDENCE FROM HOLLAND

    As regards other countries, Holland is usually described as the Mecca of Malthusians, being “the only country where Neo-Malthusianism has been given the opportunity of diminishing the excessive birth-rate on eugenic lines, i.e. in the reduction of the fertility of the poorest classes,” [38] and where a “considerable rise in the wages and general prosperity appears to have taken place side by side with an unprecedented increase of population.” When we come to investigate this claim we find that, of the eleven provinces of Holland, two are almost entirely Catholic, these being North Brabant, with 649,000 inhabitants, and Limburg, with 358,000 inhabitants. On the other hand, in Friesland, with 366,000 inhabitants, not more than 8 per cent, are Catholics. The vital statistics for 1913 are quoted by Father Thurston, S.J.:

        ”... We find that in Limburg the crude birth-rate is 33.4, in North
        Brabant it is 32.5, but in Friesland it is 24.3. Of course, this is not
        the beginning and end of the matter. In North Brabant the death-rate is
        16.36, in Limburg it is 15.28, in Friesland it is only 11.21, but the
        fact remains that in the two Catholic provinces the natural increase is
        16.17 and 18.15, while in the non-Catholic province of Friesland it is
        13.15. Further, no one can doubt that in such densely populated
        districts as North and South Holland and Gelderland the Catholics, who
        number more than 25 per cent, of the inhabitants, exercise a
        perceptible influence in raising the birth figures for the whole
        kingdom. The results would be very different if the entire country
        adopted Neo-Malthusian principles.” [39]

    Section 3. THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

    As was proved by the census of religions in 1906, the United States of America is becoming a great stronghold of the Faith. In Massachusetts the Catholic Church numbered 1,100,000 members, whereas the total membership of all the Protestant Churches was 450,000. In Illinois there were about 300,000 Methodists and 1,000,000 Catholics. There were 2,300,000 Catholics in the State of New York, and about 300,000 Methodists, while no other Protestant Church numbered more than 200,000. The New England States, once the home of American Puritanism, are now great centres of Catholicism.

    Professor Meyrick Booth [40] explains this remarkable change as being due to two causes: (1) The influx of large numbers of European Catholics, who cling tenaciously to their religion; (2) the greater fertility of these stocks as compared with the native population. Moreover, he has tabulated the following statistics:

    TABLE IV

    State. Population Chief Religious Bodies Births & Birth
                         (1906) Deaths rate per
                         (b. and d.) 1,000

    Indiana 2,700,000 Methodist 233,000 b. 36,000 13.0
                         Prot. Episcopalian 102,000 d. 36,500
                         Disciples 118,000
                         R.C. 175,000 Iowa. 2,224,000 Methodist 164,000 b. 36,000 16.0
                         Lutheran 117,000 d. 20,000
                         Presbyterian 60,000
                         R.C. 207,000 Maryland. 1,295,000 Methodist 137,000 b. 19,000 15.0
                         Prot. Episcopalian 35,000 d. 20,000
                         Baptist &smaller,
                         about 100,000
                         R.C. 167,000 California. 2,377,000 R.C. 354,000 b. 32,100 14.0
                         Prot. bodies about d. 32,400
                         (All Churches weak) 250,000 Kentucky 2,290,000 Baptist 312,000 b. 35,000 15.0
                         Methodist 156,000 d. 18,000
                         R.C. 166,000

    In these States the birth-rate is low; in three there are actually more deaths than births; and in all five the proportion of Catholics is comparatively small. These States may be compared with five others, in which the Catholic and the foreign elements are well represented:

    TABLE V

    State. Population Chief Religious Birth and Birthrate
                      (1910) Bodies Deaths per 1000

    New York. 9,113,000 R.C. 2,280,000 b. 213,000 22.0
                         Jews (?) 1,000,000 d. 147,000
                         Methodist 300,000
                         Presbyterian 200,000

    Rhode Island 540,000 R.C. 160,000 b. 13,000 24.0
                         Baptist 20,000 d. 8,000
                         Prot.
                         Episcopalian 15,000

    Massachusetts 3,336,000 R.C. 1,080,000 b. 84,000 25.0
                         Congregational 120,000 d. 51,000
                         Baptist 80,000
                         All Protestants
                         together 450,000

    Michigan 2,800,000 R.C. 490,000 b. 64,000 23.0
                         Methodist 128,000 d. 36,000
                         Lutheran 105,000

    Connecticut 1,114,000 R.C. 300,000 b. 27,000 24.0
                         Congregational 66,000 d. 17,000
                         Prot.
                         Episcopalian 37,000

    In these States the birth-rate is very much higher than in the former. Furthermore, a New York paper [40] investigated the birth-rate in that city with special reference to religious belief, and concluded that the different bodies could be graded as follows with respect to the number of children per marriage: (1) Jews, (2) Catholics, (3) Protestants (Orthodox), (4) Protestants (Liberal), and (5) Agnostic. Professor Meyrick Booth, who is himself a Protestant, concludes his survey of the evidence as follows:

        “looking at the situation as a whole, there is good reason to think
        that the Protestant Anglo-Saxons are not only losing ground
        relatively, but must, at any rate in the East and middle East, be
        suffering an actual decrease on a large scale. For it has been shown by
        more than one sociologist (see, for example, the statement in The
        Family and the Nation
    ) that no stock can maintain itself with an
        average of less than about four children per marriage, and from all
        available data (it has not been found possible to obtain definite
        figures for most of the Western and Southern States) we must see that
        the average fertility of each marriage in this section of the American
        people falls far short of the requisite four children. Judging by all
        the figures at hand, the modern Anglo-Saxon American, with his high
        standard of comfort, his intensely individualistic outlook on life, and
        his intellectual and emancipated but child-refusing wife, is being
        gradually thrust aside by the upgrowth of new masses of people of
        simpler tastes and hardier and more natural habits. And, what is of
        peculiar interest to us, this new population will carry into ascendancy
        those religious and moral beliefs which have moulded its type of life.

        “The victory will be, not to those religious beliefs which most closely
        correspond to certain requirements of the abstract intellect, but to
        those which give rise, in practice, to a mode of life that is simple,
        natural, unselfish, and adequately prolific—in other words, to a mode
        of life that works, that is Lebensfaehig.” [41]

    As things are, the original Protestant stock of America is being swamped by the growth of the Catholic, the Jewish, and the Negro population. Moreover, the United States is faced by the grave problem of a rapidly increasing coloured race. Despite this fact the American Malthusians are now demanding that a National Bureau should be established to disseminate information regarding contraceptives throughout their country! And what of the other reformers? They also are very busy. They have already abolished those cheering beverages from grapes and grain, or rather they have made alcohol one of the surreptitious privileges of the rich. They are seeking to enforce the Sabbath as a day of absolute rest, not for the glory of God but in order that tired wage-slaves may have their strength renewed for another week of toil in the factories and the mills. Again, they would uproot from the homely earth that pleasant weed whose leaves have made slaves of millions since the days of Sir Walter Raleigh. All these things would they do. There are some things the reformers have not done, and these things are recounted by an American writer, Dr. Anthony M. Benedik:

        “The divorce peril, the race-suicide evil, the greed for ill-gotten
        gold, things like these the reformers touch not. And these things it is
        which harm the soul. Abolishing the use of alcoholic drinks and of
        tobacco, putting the blue laws into effect, suppressing all rough
        sports, may make a cleaner, more sanitary, more hygienic, a quieter
        world. And yet there keep recurring to mind those words of the Master
        of mankind, 'What doth it profit a man if he gain the world and suffer
        the loss of his soul?' What worthy exchange can a man make for his
        soul?” [42]

    On the other hand, it is good to read that the Governor of New York has recently signed a bill making it a misdemeanour for landlords to refuse to rent apartments to families in which there are children. In that State children thus regain equal rights with dogs, cats, and canaries. Is it too much to ask of the House of Commons that they should pass a similar law? We shall see.

    The dangers of birth control were apparent to that great American, Theodore Roosevelt, when he said:

        “The greatest of all curses is the curse of sterility, and the severest
        of all condemnations should be that visited upon wilful sterility. The
        first essential in any civilisation is that the man and the woman shall
        be the father and the mother of healthy children, so that the race
        shall increase and not decrease.” [43]

    Section 4. THE SAME RESULTS IN ENGLAND

    On a smaller scale the position is the same in England and Wales, where Catholicism has probably checked to some extent the general decline of the birth-rate. In 1919 there were only six towns in England [44] with a birth-rate of over 25 per 1,000, these being St. Helens (25.6), Gateshead (25.9), South Shields (26.9), Sunderland (27.1), Tynemouth (25.9), and Middlesbrough (26.7). Now in these towns the Catholic element is very strong. During the same year in the four registration counties in which these towns are situated, a larger proportion of marriages were celebrated according to the rites of the Church of Rome than in the other counties of England and Wales. [45] The actual proportion of Catholic marriages per 1,000 of all marriages in these four counties was: Lancashire 116, Durham 99, Northumberland 92, and the North Riding of Yorkshire 92. That gives a fair index of the strength of the Catholic population. Again in 1919 we find that Preston, a textile town, has a birth-rate of 17.1, whereas two other textile towns, Bradford and Halifax, have rates of 13.4 and 13.1 respectively: and there can be little doubt that the relative superiority of Preston is mainly owing to her large Catholic population.

    The actual birth-rate amongst Catholics in England may be estimated from information contained in The Catholic Directory for 1914. As that work gives the Catholic population and the number of infant baptisms during the previous year in each diocese of Great Britain, and as Catholic children are always baptized soon after birth, it is possible to estimate the birth-rate of the Catholic population. Working on these figures Professor Meyrick Booth [46] has published the following table:

    TABLE VI

    Diocese. Birth-rate per 1,000 of the
                       Roman Catholic population.

    Menevia (Wales) 45.2 Middlesbrough 38.0 Leeds 42.0 Liverpool 40.0 Newport 53.0 Northampton 33.0 Plymouth 26.0 Shrewsbury 38.0 Southwark 39.O Westminster 36.0
                         —— Average 38.6
                         ——

    During the same period the general birth-rate amongst the whole population of England and Wales was about 24 per 1,000. And figures that are even more remarkable have been published by Mr. W.C.D. Whetham and Mrs. Whetham. [47] These writers, having investigated the number of children in the families of the landed gentry, show that the birth-rate amongst the aristocracy has declined.

        “A hundred fertile marriages for each decade from 1831 to 1890 have
        been taken consecutively from those families who have held their title
        to nobility for at least two preceding generations, thus excluding the
        more modern commercial middle-class element in the present Peerage,
        which can be better dealt with elsewhere. We then get the full effect
        of hereditary stability and a secure position, and do away with any
        disturbing influence that might occur from a sudden rise to
        prosperity.” [48]

    The results were as follows: [Reference: Population]

        Year. Number of children to each
        fertile marriage.

        1831-40 7.1
        1841-60 6.1
        1871-80 4.36
        1881-90 3.13

    The birth-rate amongst thirty families of the landed gentry, who were known to be definitely Catholic, was also investigated, with the following results:

        Years. Number of children to each
        fertile marriage.

        1871-90 6.6

        (as compared with 3.74 for the landed families as a whole during the
        same period.)

    The interpretation of these figures is not a matter of faith, but of reason. I submit that the facts are prima facie evidence that by observance of the moral law, as taught by the Catholic Church, even a highly cultured community is enabled to escape those dangers of over-civilisation that lead to diminished fertility and consequently to national decline.

    The truth of this statement has been freely acknowledged by many Anglicans. According to Canon Edward Lyttelton: “The discipline of the Roman Communion prohibits the artificial prevention of conception, hence Ireland is the only part of the United Kingdom in which the birth-rate has not declined, and the decline is least in places like Liverpool and those districts where Roman Catholics are most numerous.” As we have already seen, there are also other reasons why Catholicism preserves the fertility of a nation.

    Without wishing to hurt the feelings of the most sensitive materialist, it is necessary to point out that, apart altogether from the question as to whether the chief or immediate cause of a declining birth-rate is the practice of artificial birth control, or, as seems to be possible, a general lowering of fertility, birth-rates are more dependent on morals and religion than on race and country. During the past century irreligion spread throughout France, and the birth-rate fell from 32.2, during the first decade of the nineteenth century, to 20.6, during the first ten years of the twentieth century. In America, amongst the descendants of the New England Puritans a decay of religion and morals has also been accompanied by a dwindling birth-rate. The decline of the original New England stock in America has been masked to some extent by the high birth-rate amongst the immigrant population; but nevertheless it is apparent in the Census Returns for 1890, when a population of 65,000,000 was expected and only 62,500,000 was returned. Moreover, there is ample evidence in history that, wherever the Christian ideal of a family has been abandoned, a race is neither able to return to the family life of healthy pagan civilisations nor to escape decay. During the past fifty years in England family life has been definitely weakened by increased facilities for divorce amongst the rich, by the discouragement of parental authority amongst the poor, and by the neglect of all religious teaching in the schools. And thus, in the words of Charles Devas, “We have of late years, with perverse ingenuity, been preparing the way for the low birth-rate of irreligion and the high death-rate of civil disorder.” [49] The birth-rate in England and Wales reached its highest point, 36.3, in 1876, and has gradually fallen to 18.5 in 1919. During the first two quarters of that year the rate was the lowest yet recorded. During the pre-war year, 1913, the rate was 24.1.

    In conclusion, the following statements by a Protestant writer are of interest:

        “Judging from a number of figures which cannot be quoted here, owing to
        considerations of space, it would seem that the English middle-class
        birth-rate has fallen to the extent of over 50 per cent. during the
        last forty years; and we have actual figures showing that the
        well-to-do artisan birth-rate has declined, in the last thirty years,
        by 52 per cent.!
    Seeing that the Protestant Churches draw their
        members mainly from these very classes, we have not far to seek for an
        explanation of the empty Sunday Schools....”

        “Under these circumstances it is not in the least necessary for
        Protestant ministers and clergymen to cast about them for evidence of
        Jesuit machinations wherewith to explain the decline of the Protestant
        Churches in this country! Let them rather look at the empty cradles in
        the homes of their own congregations!” [50]

    The author of the above-quoted paragraphs thus attributes the decline both of the birth-rate and of the Protestant Churches to the general adoption of artificial birth control. With that explanation I disagree, because it puts the horse behind the cart. When the Protestant faith was strong the birth-rate of this country was as high as that of Catholic lands. The Protestant Churches have now been overshadowed by a rebirth of Rationalism, a growth for which they themselves prepared the soil: and diminished fertility is the natural product of a civilisation tending towards materialism. Although the practice of artificial birth control must obviously contribute towards a falling birth-rate, it is neither the only nor the ultimate cause of the decline. The ultimate causes of a falling birth-rate are more complex, and the decline of a community is but the physical expression of a moral change. That is my thesis.

    [Footnote 35: Evening Standard, October 12, 1921.]

    [Footnote 36: “The Declining Birth-rate” in The Month, August 1916, p. 157, reprinted by C.T.S. Price 2_d.]

    [Footnote 37: “Religious Belief as affecting the Growth of Population,” The Hibbert Journal, October, 1914, p. 144.]

    [Footnote 38: The Secretary of the Malthusian League. Vide The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 99.]

    [Footnote 39: The Month, August 1916, p. 157, C.T.S.: 2_d.]

    [Footnote 40: The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, p. 147.]

    [Footnote 41: The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, p. 150.]

    [Footnote 42: “Race-suicide and Dr. Bell,” America, October 29, 1921, p. 31.]

    [Footnote 43: Daily Chronicle, April 25, 1910.]

    [Footnote 44: Eighty-second Annual Report of the Registrar-General of Births, Deaths, and Marriages in England and Wales, 1919, p. 89.]

    [Footnote 45: Ibid., p. xxvi.]

    [Footnote 46: The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, p. 141.]

    [Footnote 47: The Family and the Nation, 1909, pp. 139, 142.]

    [Footnote 48: Quoted in Universe, October 22, 1921.]

    [Footnote 49: Charles S. Devas, Political Economy, 2nd edition, 1901, p. 193.]

    [Footnote 50: Meyrick Booth, B. Sc., Ph.D., The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, pp. 142 and 152.]

    CHAPTER V. IS THERE A NATURAL LAW REGULATING THE PROPORTION OF BIRTHS AND DEATHS?

    Section 1. THE THEORY OF THOMAS DOUBLEDAY REVIVED

    In 1837 Thomas Doubleday [51] maintained that the rising birth-rate of his own time was closely connected with the fall in the standard of living, and his argument implied that, in order to check the excessive birth-rate, it was necessary to improve the condition of the mass of the people. Four years later he published The True Law of Population, wherein he stated that when the existence of a species is endangered—

        “A corresponding effort is invariably made by Nature for its
        preservation and continuance by an increase of fertility, and that this
        especially takes place whenever such danger arises from a diminution of
        proper nourishment or food, so that consequently the state of depletion
        or the deplethoric state is favourable to fertility, and that, on the
        other hand, the plethoric state, or state of repletion, is unfavourable
        to fertility in the ratio of the intensity of each state.”

    By a series of experiments on plants Doubleday discovered that “whatever might be the principle of manure, an overdose of it invariably induced sterility in the plant.” Although his formula is deficient in that food is selected as the one factor in environment which influences fertility, and although it may be an overstatement to claim that fertility varies in exact proportion to abundance or to scarcity, nevertheless his formula contains an important truth which literally knocks the bottom out of the whole Malthusian case.

    It is a sad reflection that, while the falsehoods of Malthus have been blindly accepted for the greater part of a century, the work of Doubleday was almost lost in oblivion. His shade has now been recalled to the full centre of the stage, and for this the credit is due to Mr. C.E. Pell. His recent book [52] is a stimulating essay on the declining birth-rate, and contains much evidence that supports the main contention of Doubleday. Although it is impossible to agree with all the deductions made by Mr. Pell, he has nevertheless done a public service by restating the problem of the birth-rate in a new way, by effectively bursting the Malthusian bubble, and by tabulating fresh evidence against the birth-controllers.

    Section 2. MR. PELL'S GENERALISATIONS CRITICISED

    Mr. Pell defines the law of births and deaths in two generalisations. The first is: “We have seen that it is a necessary condition of the success of the evolutionary scheme that the variation of the inherited potential degree of fertility between species and species must bear an inverse proportion to their capacity for survival.” [53] At first glance this statement appears hard to be understood; but it is obviously true—because it means that a species that is well adapted to its environment can survive with a low degree of fertility, whereas a species that is not well adapted to its environment requires a high degree of fertility in order to survive. Mr. Pell considers that a “capacity for survival” is synonymous with “nervous energy”; but, as our total knowledge of nervous energy is limited to the fact that it is neither matter nor any known force, the change in words does not mark a real advance in knowledge.

    The second generalisation is that “the variation of the degree of animal fertility in response to the direct action of the environment shall bear an inverse proportion to the variation of the survival capacity under that environment.” [54] Here Mr. Pell and I part company. I have already (Chapter III) disputed the causal connection between birth-rate and death-rate which Mr. Pell here asserts. His generalisation is made by assuming that birth-rates and death-rates rise and fall together: that conditions which produce a high death-rate will also produce a high birth-rate and that conditions which cause a low death-rate will also cause a low birth-rate; that the increase or decline of a population is due to the direct action of the environment; and finally that “the actual degree of fertility is decided by the direct action of the environment.” [55] On that last rock Mr. Pell's barque sinks. The mistake here is analogous to the old Darwinian fallacy, abandoned by Huxley and by Romanes, that natural selection is a creative cause of new species. Even if the hypothesis of evolution—and it is merely a hypothesis—be accepted, the only view warranted by reason is that variation of species and their actual degree of fertility may be produced, not by the direct action of environment, but by the reaction of species to their environment—a very different story.

    There is no statistical evidence to prove a uniform correspondence between birth-rates and death-rates, and it is improbable that there should be a physical law of nature whose operations cannot be demonstrated by mathematical proof. Moreover, we know that the same conditions which cause a high birth-rate may cause a low death-rate. In the case of the first settlers in a new country the death-rate is low because the diseases of civilisation are absent and the settlers are usually young, whereas the birth-rate is high. If fifty young married couples settle on the virgin soil of a new country it is probable that for many years an enormous birth-rate, of over 100, will coexist with a low death-rate.

    In reality a high birth-rate may coexist with a low death-rate, or with a high death-rate. For example, there is a difference between natural and artificial poverty, the first being brought about by God, or, if any reader prefers to have it so, by Nature, and the second being made by man. Under conditions of natural poverty small groups of people in an open country are surrounded by land not yet cultivated: whereas artificial poverty means a population overcrowded and underfed, living in dark tenements or in back-to-back houses, breathing foul air in ill-ventilated rooms seldom lit by the sun, working long hours in gas-lit workshops for a sweated wage, buying the cheapest food in the dearest market, and drugged by bad liquor. In either case their existence is threatened, although for very different reasons, and the birth-rate rises; but under conditions of natural poverty the death-rate is low, whereas in slums the death-rate is high.

    Section 3. THE LAW OF DECLINE

    It would appear, then, that under conditions of hardship the birth-rate tends to rise, and that in circumstances of ease the birth-rate tends to fall. If the existence of the inhabitants in a closed country is threatened by scarcity, the birth-rate tends to rise. For example, “In some of the remote parts of the country, Orkney and Shetland, the population remained practically stationary between the years 1801 and 1811, and in the next ten years, still years of great scarcity, it increased 15 per cent.” [56]

    The governing principle may be expressed in the following generalisation. When the existence of a community is threatened by adversity the birth-rate tends to rise; but when the existence of a community is threatened by prosperity the birth-rate tends to fall. By adversity I mean war, famine, scarcity, poverty, oppression, an untilled soil, and disease: and by prosperity I mean wealth, luxury, idleness, a diet too rich—especially in flesh meat—and over-civilisation, whereby the physical laws of nature are defied. Now the danger of national decline owing to prosperity can be avoided by a nation that observes the moral law, and this is the most probable explanation of the fact that in Ireland, although the general prosperity of the people has rapidly increased since George Wyndham displaced landlordism over a large area by small ownership, the birth-rate has continued to rise. Moreover, the danger to national existence, as we have already indicated (Chapter I, Section. 10) is greater from moral than from physical catastrophes, and when both catastrophes are threatened the ultimate issue depends upon which of the two is the greater. Furthermore, it would appear that moral catastrophes inevitably lead to physical catastrophes. This is best illustrated by the fate of ancient Greece.

    Section 4. ILLUSTRATED FROM GREEK HISTORY [Reference: Dangers]

    The appositeness of this illustration arises from the fact that ancient Greece reached a very high level of material and intellectual civilisation, yet perished owing to moral and physical disasters.

    (a) Moral Catastrophe in Ancient Greece

    The evidence of the moral catastrophe is to be found in the change that occurred in the Greek character most definitely after the fourth century before Christ. Of this Mr. W.H.S. Jones has given the following account:

        “Gradually the Greeks lost their brilliance, which had been as the
        bright freshness of early youth. This is painfully obvious in their
        literature, if not in other forms of art. Their initiative vanished;
        they ceased to create and began to comment. Patriotism, with rare
        exceptions, became an empty name, for few had the high spirit and
        energy to translate into action man's duty to the State. Vacillation,
        indecision, fitful outbursts of unhealthy activity followed by cowardly
        depression, selfish cruelty, and criminal weakness are characteristic
        of the public life of Greece from the struggle with Macedonia to the
        final conquest by the arms of Rome. No one can fail to be struck by the
        marked difference between the period from Marathon to the Peloponnesian
        War and the period from Alexander to Mummius. Philosophy also suffered,
        and became deeply pessimistic even in the hands of its best and noblest
        exponents. 'Absence of feeling,' 'absence of care'—such were the
        highest goals of human endeavour.

        “How far this change was due to other causes is a complicated question.
        The population may have suffered from foreign admixture during the
        troubled times that followed the death of Alexander. There were,
        however, many reasons against the view that these disturbances produced
        any appreciable difference of race. The presence of vast numbers of
        slaves, not members of households, but the gangs of toilers whom the
        increase of commerce brought into the country, pandered to a foolish
        pride that looked upon many kinds of honourable labour as being
        shameful and unbecoming to a free man. The very institution that made
        Greek civilisation possible encouraged idleness, luxury, and still
        worse vices. Unnatural vice, which in some States seems to have been
        positively encouraged, was prevalent among the Greeks to an almost
        incredible extent. It is hard not to believe that much physical harm
        was caused thereby; of the loss to moral strength and vigour there is
        no need to speak. The city-state, again, however favourable to the
        development of public spirit and a sense of responsibility, was doomed
        to fail in a struggle against the stronger Powers of Macedon and Rome.
        The growth of the scientific spirit destroyed the old religion. The
        more intellectual tried to find principles of conduct in philosophy;
        the ignorant or half-educated, deprived of the strong moral support
        that always comes from sharing the convictions of those abler and wiser
        than oneself, fell back upon degrading superstitions. In either case
        there was a serious loss of that spirit of self-sacrifice and devotion
        which a vigorous religious faith alone can bestow. Without such a
        spirit, as history proves conclusively, no nation or people can
        survive.” [57]

    (b) The Physical Catastrophe induced by Selfishness

    One of the physical catastrophes that probably most accelerated the fall of Greek civilisation was malarial fever. The parasite of this disease is carried from man to man by Anopheline mosquitoes. These insects, during the stage of egg, larva, and nympha, live in water, and afterwards, as developed insects, in the air. The breeding-grounds, where the eggs are laid, are shallow pools of stagnant water. For that reason the disease is most common in marshy country, and tends to disappear when the land is properly drained. Of this we have an example in England, whence malaria disappeared as the marshes were drained.

    In Homer there is a disputed reference to malaria, but it is not possible to ascertain whether the disease was present during the rise of Greek civilisation, and there are no references to this disease in the literature from 700 B.C. to 550 B.C. [58] From this date references to malaria gradually become more frequent, and Hippocrates stated that “those who live in low, moist, hot districts, and drink the stagnant water, of necessity suffer from enlarged spleen. They are stunted and ill-shaped, fleshy and dark, bilious rather than phlegmatic. Their nature is to be cowardly and adverse from hardship; but good discipline can improve their character in this respect.” [59] After an exhaustive study of the literature, Mr. Jones concludes “that malaria was endemic throughout the greater part of the Greek world by 400 B.C.”

    Concerning the causes of a malarial epidemic, Sir Ronald Ross writes: [60] “Suppose that the Anophelines have been present from the first, but that the number of infected immigrants has been few. Then, possibly, some of these people have happened to take up their abode in places where the mosquitoes are rare; others may have recovered quickly; others may not have chanced to possess parasites in suitable stages when they have been bitten. Thus, the probability of their spreading infection would be very small. Or, supposing even that some few new infections have been caused, yet, by our rough calculations in section 12, unless the mosquitoes are sufficiently numerous in the locality, the little epidemic may die out after a while—for instance, during the cool season.” The italics are mine, because some writers have suggested that the decline of Greece was due to malaria, whereas I submit, as the more logical interpretation of the facts, that a moral catastrophe led to the neglect of agriculture, whereby the area of marshy land became more extensive, mosquitoes more numerous, and the fever more prevalent.

    In view of the foregoing facts, the following Malthusian statement, although groundless, is nevertheless an amusing example of the errors that arise from lack of a little knowledge:

        “The difficulty of providing for a high birth-rate in a settled
        community was appreciated by the ancient Greeks, notably by Plato and
        Aristotle; but their conclusions were swept aside by the warlike spirit
        of Rome, and the sentimentality of Christianity, so that only a few
        isolated thinkers showed any appreciation of them.” [61]

    [Footnote 51: Quoted in The Law of Births and Deaths, by Charles Edward Pell, 1921, chap. xii.]

    [Footnote 52: The Law of Births and Deaths, 1921.]

    [Footnote 53: Ibid., p. 40.]

    [Footnote 54: The Law of Births and Deaths, 1921, p. 41.]

    [Footnote 55: Ibid., p. 40.]

    [Footnote 56: Dr. John Brownlee, The Declining Birth-rate, p. 156.]

    [Footnote 57: Malaria and Greek History, 1909, pp. 102 et seq.]

    [Footnote 58: Ibid., p. 26.]

    [Footnote 59: Ibid., p. 85.]

    [Footnote 60: Report on the Prevention of Malaria in Mauritius, p. 51.]

    [Footnote 61: C.V. Drysdale, O.B.E., D. Sc., The Malthusian Doctrine and its Modern Aspects, p. 3.]

    CHAPTER VI. THE FALLING BIRTH-RATE IN ENGLAND: ITS CAUSES

    Birth controllers claim that the fall in the English birth-rate, which began to decline in 1876, is mostly due to the use of contraceptives: but the very fact that this claim is made by these reckless propagandists makes it imperative that we should scrutinise the evidence very carefully.

    Section 1. NOT, AS MALTHUSIANS ASSERT, DUE MAINLY TO CONTRACEPTIVES

    In support of the Malthusian contention, Dr. C.V. Drysdale, who is not a doctor of medicine but a doctor of science, has published the following statements:

        ”... We might note that a recent investigation of the records of the
        Quakers (the Society of Friends) reveals the fact that family
        limitation has been adopted by them to a most astonishing extent. Their
        birthrate [sic] stood at 20 per thousand in 1876, and has now
        actually fallen to about 8 per thousand. The longevity of Quakers is
        well known, and the returns of deaths given by their Society show that
        the great majority live to between seventy and ninety years. Infantile
        mortality is practically unknown among them, although none of the
        special steps so dear to most social reformers have been taken for the
        protection of infant life. The Quakers are well known to be very
        earnest Christians, and to give the best example of religious morality.
        Their probity in business and their self-sacrifice in humanitarian work
        of all kinds are renowned. Yet it would seem that they have adopted
        family restriction to a greater extent than any other body of people,
        and, since the decline of their birth-rate only began in 1876, that it
        is due to adoption of preventive methods.” [62]

    Again, he translates the following quotation from a Swiss author:

        “In France a national committee has been formed which has as its object
        an agitation for the increase of the population. Upon this committee
        these [? there] sit, besides President Poincare, who, although married,
        has no children, twenty-four senators and litterateurs. These
        twenty-five persons, who preach to their fellow citizens by word and
        pen, have between them nineteen children, or not one child on the
        average per married couple. Similarly, a Paris journal
        (Intransigeant, August and September, 1908) had the good idea of
        publishing four hundred and forty-five names of the chief Parisian
        personalities who are never tired of lending their names in support of
        opposition to the artificial restriction of families. I give these
        figures briefly without the names, which have no special interest for
        us. Anyone interested in the names can consult the paper well known in
        upper circles. Among them:

              176 married couples had 0 children = 0 children
              106 ” ” ” 1 child = 106 “
              88 ” ” ” 2 children = 176 “
              40 ” ” ” 3 ” = 120 “
              19 ” ” ” 4 ” = 76 “
                7 ” ” ” 5 ” = 35 “
                4 ” ” ” 6 ” = 24 “
                3 ” ” ” 7 ” = 21 “
                1 ” ” ” 9 ” = 9 “
                1 ” ” ” 11 ” = 11 “

        Total 445 with 578

        That is, an average one and a third children per couple, while each
        single one of these families could much more easily have supported
        twenty children than a working-class family a single child.”

    “Comment on the above is superfluous,” adds Dr. C.V. Drysdale, and with that remark most people will cordially disagree. The obvious interpretation of the foregoing figures is that there has been a decline in natural fertility amongst highly educated and civilised people. But that interpretation does not suit Dr. Drysdale's book, and hence we have the disgraceful spectacle of a writer who, in order to bolster up an argument which is rotten from beginning to end, does not hesitate to launch without a particle of evidence a charge of gross hypocrisy against the Quakers of England, a body of men and women who in peace and in war have proved the sincerity of their faith, and against four hundred and seventy respected citizens of Paris. Further comment on that is superfluous. At the same time it is obvious that, in so far as their pernicious propaganda spreads and is adopted, Malthusians may claim to contribute to the fall of the birth-rate, and towards the decline of the Empire.

    Section 2. DECLINE IN FERTILITY DUE TO SOME NATURAL LAW

    In the course of an inquiry on the fertility of women who had received a college education, the National Birth Rate Commission [63] attempted to discover to what extent birth control was practised amongst the middle and professional classes. Of those amongst whom the inquiry was made 477 gave definite answers, from which it was ascertained that 289, or 60 per cent., consciously limited their families, or attempted to do so; and that 188, or 40 per cent. made no attempt to limit their families. Amongst those who limited their families 183 stated the means employed, and of these, 105, or 57 per cent., practised continence, whilst 78, or 43 per cent., used artificial or unnatural methods.

    Now comes a most extraordinary fact. Dr. Major Greenwood, [64] a statistician whose methods are beyond question, discovered that there was no real mathematical difference between the number of children in the “limited” families and the number in the unlimited families. In both groups of families the number of children was smaller than the average family in the general population, and in both groups there were fewer children than in the families of the preceding generation to which the parents belonged. Dr. Greenwood states that this is prima facie evidence that deliberate birth control has produced little effect, and that the lowered fertility is the expression of a natural change. Nevertheless, he holds that the latter explanation cannot be accepted as wholly proved on the evidence, owing to certain defects in the data on which his calculations were based.

        “I am of opinion that we should hesitate before adopting that
        interpretation in view of the cogent indirect evidence afforded by
        other data that the fall of the birth-rate is differential, and that
        the differentiation is largely economic. There are at least two
        considerations which must be borne in mind in connection with these
        schedules. The first is, that all the marriages described as unlimited
        may not have been so. I do not suggest that the answers are
        intentionally false, but it is possible that many may have considered
        that limitation implied the use of mechanical means; that marriages in
        which the parties merely abstained from, or limited the occasions of,
        sexual intercourse may have frequently entered as of unrestricted
        fertility.”

    The above italics are mine, because, if that surmise be correct, it goes to prove that the restriction of intercourse to certain periods, which restriction the married may lawfully practise, is as efficacious in limiting the size of a family as are those artificial methods of birth control contrary both to natural and to Christian morality. Dr. Major Greenwood continues as follows:

        “In the second place, the schedules do not provide us with information
        as to when limitation was introduced. We are told, for instance, that
        the size of the family was five and that its number was limited. This
        may mean either that throughout the duration of the marriage
        preventive measures were adopted from time to time, or that after
        five children had been born fertile intercourse was stopped. In the
        absence of detailed information on this point it is plainly impossible
        to form an accurate judgment as to the effect of limitation.”

    There are, therefore, no accurate figures to indicate the extent to which birth control has contributed to the decline in the birth-rate.

    Section 3. AND TO CHARACTER OF OCCUPATION

    Moreover the claim of birth controllers, that the decline in the English birth-rate is mainly due to the use of contraceptives, is rendered highly improbable by the fact that the Registrar-General [65] has shown that in 1911 the birth-rate in different classes varied according to the occupation of the fathers. The figures are these:

                         Births per 1,000 married
            Social Class. males aged under 55, including
                         retired.

        1. Unskilled workmen 213
        2. Intermediate class 158
        3. Skilled workmen 153
        4. Intermediate 132
        5. Upper and middle class 119

    Thus, ascending the social scale, we find, in class upon class, that as the annual income increases the number of children in the family diminishes, until we come to the old English nobility of whom, according to Darwin, 19 per cent. are childless. These last have every reason to wish for heirs to inherit their titles and what land and wealth they possess, and, as their record in war proves them to be no cowards' breed, it would be a monstrous indictment to maintain that their childlessness is mostly due to the use of contraceptives. If all these results arose from the practice of birth control, it would imply a crescendo of general national selfishness unparalleled in the history of humanity. No, it is not possible to give Neo-Malthusians credit, even for all the evil they claim to have achieved.

    Section 4. AGGRAVATED DOUBTLESS BY MALTHUSIANISM

    Nevertheless, artificial birth control is an evil and too prevalent thing. My contention is that the primary cause of our falling birth-rate is over-civilisation; one of the most evil products of this over-civilisation, whereby simple, natural, and unselfish ideals, based on the assumption that national security depends on the moral and economic strength of family life, have been replaced largely by a complicated, artificial, and luxurious individualism; and that diminished fertility, apart from the practice of artificial birth control, is a result of luxurious individualism. Even if it be so, one of the most evil products of over-civilisation is the use of contraceptives, because this practice, more than any other factor in social life, hastens, directly and indirectly, the fall of a declining birth-rate; and artificial birth control, to the extent to which it is practised, therefore aggravates the consequences of a law of decline already apparent in our midst. I have already said that restriction of intercourse, as held lawful by the Catholic Church, is possibly as efficacious in limiting the size of a family as are artificial methods. If any man shall say that therefore there is no difference between these methods, let him read the fuller explanation given in another connection on p. 153. (See [Reference: Explanation]) The method which reason and morality alike permit is devoid of all those evils, moral, psychological, and physiological, that follow the use of contraceptives.

    [Footnote 62: The Small Family System, pp. 195 and 160, New York, 1917.]

    [Footnote 63: The Declining Birth-rate, p. 323.]

    [Footnote 64: The Declining Birth-rate, p. 324.]

    [Footnote 65: The Declining Birth-rate, p. 9.]

    CHAPTER VII. THE EVILS OF ARTIFICIAL BIRTH CONTROL

    Section 1. NOT A PHYSICAL BENEFIT

    Birth control is alleged to be beneficial for men and women, and these “benefits” are no less amazing than the fallacies on which this practice is advocated. At the Obstetric Section of the Royal Society of Medicine in 1921 the leading physicians on diseases of women condemned the use of contraceptives. [66]

        A Cause of Sterility

        Dr. R.A. Gibbons, Physician to the Grosvenor Hospital for Women, said
        that nowadays it was common for a young married woman to ask her
        medical man for advice as to the best method of preventing conception.
        The test of relative sterility was the rapidity with which conception
        takes place. He had made confidential inquiries in 120 marriages. In
        100 cases preventive measures had been used at one time or another, and
        the number of children was well under 2 per marriage. In Paris some
        time ago the birth-rate was 104 per 1,000 in the poorer quarters and
        only 34 in a rich quarter of the city; in London comparative figures
        had been given as 195 and 63 in poor and in rich quarters. These and
        similar figures showed that women living in comfort and luxury did not
        want to be bothered with confinements. It had been said that the degree
        of sterility could be regarded as an index to the morals of a race.
        Congenital sterility was rare, but the number of children born in
        England was decreasing. It had been estimated that one-third of the
        pregnancies in several great cities abroad aborted. Dr. Gibbons then
        quoted figures given by Douglas Wight and Amand Routh to show the high
        percentage of abortions and stillbirths. In his opinion it was the duty
        of medical men to point out to the public that physiological laws could
        not be broken with impunity. It had been observed that if the doe were
        withheld from the buck at oestral periods atrophy of the ovary took
        place. In this connection Dr. Gibbons recalled a large number of
        patients who had used contraceptives in early married life, and
        subsequently had longed in vain for a child. This applied also to those
        who had decided, after the first baby, to have no more children, and
        had subsequently regretted their decision.

        Neuroses

        Professor McIlroy, of the London School of Medicine for Women, deplored
        the amount of time spent on attempting to cure sterility when
        contraceptives were so largely used. The fact that neuroses were
        largely the result of the use of contraceptives should be made widely
        known, and also that in women the maternal passion was even stronger,
        though it might develop later, than sexual passion, and would
        ultimately demand satisfaction.

        Fibroid Tumours

        Dr. Arthur E. Giles, Senior Surgeon to the Chelsea Hospital for Women,
        endorsed Dr. Gibbons's remarks as to the great unhappiness resulting
        from deliberately childless marriages, and he added that he had always
        warned patients of this. He believed that quinine had a permanently bad
        effect. Those who waited for a convenient season to have a child often
        laid up trouble for themselves. On the question of fibroid tumours he
        had come to the conclusion that these were not a cause but in a sense a
        consequence of sterility. Women who were subjected to sexual excitement
        with no physiological outlet appear to have a tendency to develop
        fibroids. He would like the opinion to go forth from the section that
        the use of contraceptives was a bad thing.

    All these authorities are agreed that the practice of artificial sterility during early married life is the cause of many women remaining childless, although later on these women wish in vain for children. To meet this difficulty one of the advocates of birth control advises all young couples to make sure of some children before adopting these practices; thus demanding of young parents, at the very time when it is most irksome, that very sacrifice of personal comfort and prosperity to prevent which is the precise object of the vicious practice. Nor is sterility the only penalty. The disease known as neurasthenia arises both in women and in men in consequence of these methods. Dr. Mary Sharlieb, [67] after forty years' experience of diseases of women, writes as follows:

        “Now, on the surface of things, it would seem as if a knowledge of how
        to prevent the too rapid increase of a family would be a boon to
        over-prolific and heavily burdened mothers. There are, however, certain
        reasons which probably convert the supposed advantage into a very real
        disadvantage. An experience of well over forty years convinces me that
        the artificial limitation of the family causes damage to a woman's
        nervous system. The damage done is likely to show itself in inability
        to conceive when the restriction voluntarily used is abandoned because
        the couple desire offspring.

        “I have for many years asked women who came to me desiring children
        whether they have ever practised prevention, and they very frequently
        tell me that they did so during the early days of their married life
        because they thought that their means were not adequate to the support
        of a family. Subsequently they found that conception, thwarted at the
        time that desire was present, fails to occur when it becomes
        convenient. In such cases, even although examination of the pelvic
        organ shows nothing abnormal, all one's endeavours to secure conception
        frequently go unrewarded. Sometimes such a woman is not only sterile,
        but nervous, and in generally poor health; but the more common
        occurrence is that she remains fairly well until the time of the change
        of life, when she frequently suffers more, on the nervous side, than
        does the woman who has lived a natural married life.”

    The late Dr. F.W. Taylor, President of the British Gynaecological Society, wrote as follows in 1904:

        “Artificial prevention is an evil and a disgrace. The immorality of it,
        the degradation of succeeding generations by it, their domination or
        subjection by strangers who are stronger because they have not given
        way to it, the curses that must assuredly follow the parents of
        decadence who started it,—all of this needs to be brought home to the
        minds of those who have thoughtlessly or ignorantly accepted it, for it
        is to this undoubtedly that we have to attribute not only the
        diminishing birth-rate, but the diminishing value of our population.

        “It would be strange indeed if so unnatural a practice, one so
        destructive of the best life of the nation, should bring no danger or
        disease in its wake, and I am convinced, after many years of
        observation, that both sudden danger and chronic disease may be
        produced by the methods of prevention very generally employed.... The
        natural deduction is that the artificial production of modern times,
        the relatively sterile marriage, is an evil thing, even to the
        individuals primarily concerned, injurious not only to the race, but to
        those who accept it.”

    That was the opinion of a distinguished gynaecologist, who also happened to be a Christian. The reader may protest that the latter fact is entirely irrelevant to my argument, and that the value of a man's observations concerning disease is to be judged by his skill and experience as a physician, and not by his religious beliefs. A most reasonable statement. Unhappily, the Neo-Malthusians think otherwise. They would have us believe that because this man was a Christian his opinion, as a gynaecologist, is worthless. C.V. Drysdale, O.B.E., D. Sc., after quoting Dr. Taylor's views, adds the following foot-note:

        “I have since learnt that Dr. Taylor was a very earnest Christian, and
        the author of several sacred hymns and of a pious work, The Coming of
        the Saints
    .” [68]

    Furthermore, in 1905, the South-Western Branch of the British Medical Association passed the following resolution:

        “That this Branch is of opinion that the growing use of contraceptives
        and ecbolics is fraught with great danger both to the individual and to
        the race. That this Branch is of opinion that the advertisements and
        sale of such appliances and substances, as well as the publication and
        dissemination of literature relating thereto, should be made a penal
        offence.” [69]

    Section 2. A SCANDALOUS SUGGESTION

    The foregoing opinions are very distasteful to Neo-Malthusians, and these people, being unable apparently to give a reasoned answer, do not hesitate to suggest that medical opposition, when not due to religious bias, is certainly due to mercenary motives.

        “As the Church has a vested interest in souls, so the medical
        profession has a vested interest in bodies. Birth is a source of
        revenue, direct and indirect. It means maternity fees first; it
        generally presupposes preliminary medical treatment of the expectant
        mother; and it provides a new human being to be a patient to some
        member of the profession, humanly certain to have its share of
        infantile diseases, and likely, if it survives them, to produce
        children of its own before the final death-bed attendance is
        reached.” [70]

    That scandalous suggestion has recently been repeated by the President of the Society for Constructive Birth Control and Racial Progress under the following circumstances. On October 31, 1921, the Sussex Daily News published the following paragraph from its London correspondent.

        “BIRTH CONTROL

        “Reverberations of Lord Dawson's recent sensational address to the
        Church Congress on birth control are still being felt as well in
        medical as in clerical circles. Indeed, the subject has been discussed
        by the lawyers at Gray's Inn. The London Association of the Medical
        Women's Federation had so animated a discussion on it that it was
        decided to continue it at the next meeting. It is quite evident that
        Lord Dawson did not speak for a united medical profession. Indeed,
        quite a number of doctors of all creeds are attacking the new Birth
        Control Society. A London physician has a pamphlet on the subject in
        the Press, and the controversy rages fiercely in the neighbourhood of
        'birth-control' clinics. Much is likely to be made of the example of
        France, where the revolt against the practices advocated is now in full
        swing, and strong legal measures have been taken and are in
        contemplation. French medical opinion is said to be very pronounced on
        the subject, and it has, of course, a great deal of clinical experience
        to back it.”

    On November 8, a second paragraph appeared:

        “BIRTH CONTROL

        “My remark recently that 'a number of doctors of all creeds are
        attacking the new Birth-Control Society' has been challenged by the
        hon. secretary of the body in question, who observes that I am
        misinformed. I must adhere to my statement, which was a record of
        personal observation. Many doctors have spoken to me on the subject,
        and their opinions on the ethics of birth control differ widely; but I
        can only remember one who did not attack this particular society. The
        secretary suggests that I am confusing what his society advocates with
        something else. As a matter of fact, the whole question of birth
        control has been discussed more than once by medical bodies. A doctor
        who attended one such discussion shortly after the opening of the
        clinic in Holloway told me that, while there was division of opinion on
        the general subject, the feeling of the meeting was overwhelming
        against the particular teaching given at the clinic, as undesirable and
        actively mischievous. The subject is controversial, and I profess to do
        no more than record such opinions as are current.”

    On November 17 the Sussex Daily News published the following letter:

        “CONSTRUCTIVE BIRTH CONTROL

        “Sir,—Your recent paragraph of 'opinions' about the Mothers' Clinic
        and the Society for Constructive Birth Control and Racial Progress is
        not only extremely unrepresentative, but grossly misleading. Your
        writer says that he can only remember one doctor who did not attack
        this particular society. This implies that the medical profession is
        against it, which is absolutely untrue, as is quite evident from the
        fact that we have three of the most distinguished medical men in Great
        Britain on our list of Vice-Presidents; four others, also very
        distinguished, on our Research Committee; and that Dr. E.B. Turner, in
        a Press interview after the recent Church Congress, singled out
        Constructive Birth Control as the only 'Control' which was not
        mischievous.

        “That there may be medical men who do not approve of birth control is
        natural, when one remembers that a doctor has to make his living, and
        can do so more easily when women are ailing with incessant pregnancies
        than when they maintain themselves in good health by only having
        children when fitted to do so. Opinions of medicals, therefore, must be
        sifted. The best doctors are with us; the self-seeking and the biassed
        may be against us
    .

        “Details about the society, including the manifesto signed by a series
        of the most distinguished persons, can be obtained on application to
        the Honorary Secretary, at ... London, N.19.—Yours, etc.

        “MARIE C. STOPES,
        “President Society for Constructive and Racial Progress.”

    The italics are mine, and they draw attention to a disgraceful statement concerning the medical profession. As the reader is aware, certain members of our profession approve of artificial birth control. What, I ask, would be the opinion of the general public, and of my friends, if I were so distraught as to suggest that these men approved of birth control because they had a financial interest in the sale of contraceptives? That suggestion would be as reckless and as wicked as the statement made by Dr. Marie C. Stopes. In the British Medical Journal of November 26 I quoted, without comment, the above italicised paragraph as her opinion of the medical profession, and on December 10 the following reply from the lady appeared:

        “Your two correspondents, Dr. Halliday Sutherland and Dr. Binnie
        Dunlop, by quoting paragraphs without their full context, appear to
        lend support to views which by implication are, to some extent,
        detrimental to my own. This method of controversy has never appealed to
        me, but in the interests of the society with which I am associated, I
        must be allowed to answer the implications. The paragraph quoted by Dr.
        Sutherland is not, as would appear from his letter, a simple opinion of
        mine on the medical profession, but was written in reply to a rather
        scurrilous paragraph so worded as to lead the public to believe that
        the medical profession as a whole was against the Society for
        Constructive Birth Control and Racial Progress. My answer, which
        appeared not only in the papers quoted but in others, contained the
        following statement: 'We have three of the most distinguished medical
        men in Great Britain on our list of Vice-Presidents; four others, also
        very distinguished, on our Research Committee.' Reading these words
        before the paragraph your correspondent quotes, and taking all in
        conjunction with an attack implying that the entire medical profession
        was against us, it is obvious that the position is rather different
        from what readers of Dr. Sutherland's letter in your issue of November
        26 might suppose.”

    It will be noted that Dr. Stopes does not withdraw but attempts to justify her scandalous suggestion by stating, firstly, that the full context of her letter was not quoted by me, and secondly, that her original letter was written “in reply to a rather scurrilous paragraph.”

    As I have now quoted in full her original letter, excepting the address of her society, and the two paragraphs from the Sussex Daily News, my readers may form their own judgment on the following points: Is it possible to maintain that the whole context of her original letter puts a different complexion on her remarks concerning the medical profession? Can either of the paragraphs from the Sussex Daily News be truthfully described as “rather scurrilous,” or are they fair comment on a matter of public interest? Moreover, even if a daily paper had published a misleading paragraph about this society, surely that is not a valid reason why its President should make a malignant attack, not on journalists, but on the medical profession?

    Section 3. A CAUSE OF UNHAPPINESS IN MARRIAGE

    Nor does birth control lead to happiness in marriage. On the contrary, experience shows that the practice is injurious not only to the bodies but also to the minds of men and women. As no method of contraception is infallible, the wife who allows or adopts it may find herself in the truly horrible position of being secretly or openly suspected of infidelity. Again, when a family has been limited to one or two children and these die, the parents may find themselves solitary and childless in old age; and mothers thus bereaved are often the victims of profound and lasting melancholy. The mother of a large family has her worries, many of them not due to her children, but to the social evils of our time: and yet she is less to be pitied than the woman who is losing her beauty after a fevered life of, vanity and self-indulgence, and who has no one to love her, not even a child.

    Moreover, these practices have an influence on the relation between husband and wife, on their emotions towards each other and towards the whole sexual nisus. Mr. Bernard Shaw recently stated [71] that when people adopt methods of birth control they are engaging, not in sexual intercourse, but in reciprocal masturbation.

    That is the plain truth of the matter. Or, from another point of view, it may be said that the man who adopts these practices is simply using his wife as he would use a prostitute, as indeed was said long ago by St. Thomas Aquinas. [72] The excuse offered for illicit sexual intercourse is not usually pleasure, but that the sex impulse is irresistible: and the same argument is used for conjugal union with prevention. In both cases the natural result of union is not desired, and positive means are taken to prevent it.

    And what of the results on the mutual love, if an old-fashioned word be not now out of place, and on the self-respect of two people so associated? Birth control cannot make for happiness, because it means that mutual love is at the mercy of an animal instinct, neither satisfied nor denied. It is an old truth that those who seek happiness for itself never find it. And yet the advocates of birth control have the temerity to claim that these practices lead to happiness. I presume that of the bliss following marriage with contraceptives the crowded lists of our divorce courts are an index. The marriage bond is weakened when a common lasting interest in the care of children is replaced by transient sexual excitement. Once pregnancy is abolished there is no natural check on the sexual passions of husband or wife, for they have learnt how sexual desire may be gratified without the pain, publicity, and responsibility of having children. In the experience of the world marriages based merely on passion are seldom happy, and artificial birth control means passion uncontrolled by nature. These methods are not practised by nations such as Ireland and Spain, who accept the moral rule of the natural law expressed in God's commandments and sanctioned by His judgments; and no man who has ever lived in these countries could truthfully maintain that the people there, on whom the burdens of marriage press as elsewhere, are in reality anxious to obtain facilities for divorce. On the other hand, there are many who allege that the people of England are shouting out for greater facilities for divorce than they now possess. At any rate, it is obvious enough that there are those amongst us who are straining every nerve to force such facilities upon them.

    Section 4. AN INSULT TO TRUE WOMANHOOD

    It has been said that patriotism is the last refuge of a scoundrel; and apparently chivalry is the last refuge of a fool. Some of the advocates of birth control who have never thought the matter out, either passionately or dispassionately, claim to speak on behalf of women. They protest that “many women of the educated classes revolt against the drudgery, anxieties, inconveniences, disease, and disfigurements which attend the yearly child-bearing advocated by the moralist.” [73]

    What moralist? Who ever said it? Again, they plead for women who “revolt” from the “disfigurement” of the gestation period. The great artist Botticelli did not think this was disfigurement. What true women do? Are they not those of whom Kipling writes, “as pale and as stale as a bone”? And, if so, are these unworthy specimens of their sex worth tears? The vast majority of women bear the discomforts of gestation and the actual perils and pangs of birth with exemplary fortitude: and it is a gross slander for anyone to maintain that a few cowardly and degenerate individuals really represent that devoted sex. But these writers are indeed well out of the ruck of ordinary humanity, because they tell us that “whatever the means employed, and whether righteous or not, the propensity to limit the highest form of life operates silently and steadily amongst the more thoughtful members of all civilized countries,” and yet add that “it is not perhaps good taste to consider the means employed to this end.” While they thus approve and commend the practice of birth control as natural to “the more thoughtful members,” they nevertheless question the “good taste” of discussing the very methods of which they approve, even in the columns of a medical journal! Again, they tell us that “assuredly continence is not, and never will be, the principal” method. That may be possibly true, so long as Christianity is more professed than practised; God knows we are all lacking enough in self-control. And yet throughout the ages moralists have preached the advantages of self-control, and we ordinary men and women know that we could do better, and that others who have gone before us have done better; but it is the self-styled “thoughtful members” who proclaim to the world that self-control in matters of sex is an impossibility, and therefore not to be even attempted. They are no common people—these epicureans, selfish even in their refinement. In addition to losing their morals, they have certainly lost their wits.

    Section 5. A DEGRADATION OF THE FEMALE SEX

    In the Neo-Malthusian propaganda there is yet another fact which—should be seized by every married woman, because it is a clear indication of a tendency to reduce women to degrading subjection. No recommendations of limited intercourse or of self-restraint according to the dictates of reason or of affection are to be found in the writings of birth controllers. Unrestrained indulgence, without the risk of consequences, is their motto. To this end they advocate certain contraceptive methods, and the reader should note that these methods require precautions to be taken solely by the woman. If she fails to take these precautions, or if the precautions themselves fail, all responsibility for the occurrence of conception rests on her alone; because her Malthusian masters have decided that she alone is to be, made responsible for preventing the natural or possible consequences of intercourse. Why? That is a very interesting question, and one to which a leading Neo-Malthusian has given the answer.

    In 1854 there was published, Physical, Sexual and Natural Religion: by a Graduate of Medicine. In the third edition the title was altered to The Elements of Social Science, and the author's pseudonym to A Doctor of Medicine. This book, which contains over 600 pages of small type, may be truthfully described as the Bible of Neo-Malthusians, and includes, under the curious heading Sexual Religion, a popular account of all venereal and other diseases of sex. In the Preface to the first edition, [74] the anonymous author states: “Had it not been the fear of causing pain to a relation, I should have felt it my duty to put my name to this work; in order that any censure passed upon it should fall upon myself alone.” The relation appears to have had a long life, because anonymity was preserved for fifty years, presumably out of respect for his, or her, feelings: and he, or she, must have lived as long as the author, who died in 1904 at the age of seventy-eight; because the author's name was not revealed until a posthumous edition, the thirty-fifth, appeared in 1905, from which we learn that the book was written by the late Dr. George Drysdale, brother of the first President of the Malthusian League, and uncle of the present incumbent. The last edition, in recompense for its smudgy type, contains a most welcome announcement by the publisher:

        “PUBLISHER'S NOTE.—... It is due alike to the reader and the publisher
        to explain why the present edition is printed (in the main) from
        stereotypes that have seen fifty years' service. The cost of resetting
        the work would be prohibitive on the basis of present (and probable
        future) sales. To some extent the plates have been repaired; but such
        an expedient can do no more than remove the worse causes of offence.”

    But the fact with which I am at present concerned is that in every edition all contraceptive methods that apply to the male are condemned for the following reasons:

        “The first of these modes [coitus interruptus] is physically
        injurious, and is apt to produce nervous disorder and sexual
        enfeeblement and congestion, from the sudden interruption it gives to
        the venereal act, whose pleasure moreover it interferes with. The
        second, namely the sheath, dulls the enjoyment, and frequently
        produces impotence in the man and disgust in both parties; so that it
        also is injurious” (p. 349).... “Any preventive means, to be
        satisfactory, must be used by the woman, as it spoils the passion and
        the impulsiveness
    of the venereal act if the man have to think of
        them
    ” (p. 350).

    The italics are mine, but the following comments are by a woman, who was moreover the first woman to qualify in medicine—the late Dr. Elizabeth Blackwell.

        “Here, in this chief teacher of the Neo-Malthusians, the cloven foot is
        fully revealed. This popular author, who in many parts of his book
        denounces marriage as the enslavement of men and women, who sneers at
        continence, and rages at Christianity as a vanishing superstition—all
        under a special pretence of benevolence and desire for the advancement
        of the human race, here clearly, shows what he is aiming at, and what
        his doctrines lead to. Male sexual pleasure must not be interfered
        with, male lust may be indulged in to any extent that pleasure demands,
        but woman must take the entire responsibility, that male indulgence be
        not disturbed by any inconvenient claims from paternity. Whatever
        consequences ensue the woman is to blame, and must bear the whole
        responsibility.

        “A doctrine more diabolical in its theory and more destructive in its
        practical consequences has never been invented. This is the doctrine of
        Neo-Malthusianism.” [75]

    Section 6. SPECIALLY HURTFUL TO THE POOR

    (a) Affecting the Young

    There are three special and peculiar evils that attend the teaching of birth control amongst the poor. Of the first a doctor has written as follows:

        “Morally, the doctrine is indefensible—it follows the line of least
        resistance, and sacrifices the spirit to the flesh. Materially, it is
        fraught with grave danger to the home and to our national existence. It
        is proposed to disseminate a knowledge of contraceptive methods
        throughout the overcrowded homes of the ill-fed, ill-clad poor. Now it
        is in these homes that the moral sense has already but little chance of
        development, where the child of eight or ten already knows far more
        than is good for the health of either body or mind, and, though we may
        succeed in reducing the size of the family, yet the means we employ
        will militate against the raising of the moral tone of the household,
        and the children will not be any less precocious than before.” [76]

    That danger is ignored by the advocates of birth-control. “But he that shall scandalise one of these little ones that believe in Me, it were better for, him that a mill-stone were hanged about his neck, and that he were drowned in the depth, of the sea.” [77]

    (b) Exposing the Poor to Experiment

    Secondly, the ordinary decent instincts of the poor are against these practices, and indeed they have used them less than any other class. But, owing to their poverty, lack of learning, and helplessness, the poor are the natural victims of those who seek to make experiments on their fellows. In the midst of a London slum a woman, who is a doctor of German philosophy (Munich), has opened a Birth Control Clinic, where working women are instructed in a method of contraception described by Professor McIlroy as “the most harmful method of which I have had experience.” [78] When we remember that millions are being spent by the Ministry of Health and by Local Authorities—on pure milk for necessitous expectant and nursing mothers, on Maternity Clinics to guard the health of mothers before and after childbirth, for the provision of skilled midwives, and on Infant Welfare Centres—all for the single purpose of bringing healthy children into our midst, it is truly amazing that this monstrous campaign of birth control should be tolerated by the Home Secretary. Charles Bradlaugh was condemned to jail for a less serious crime.

    (c) Tending towards the Servile State

    Thirdly, the policy of birth control opens the way to an extension of the Servile State, [79] because women as well as men could then be placed under conditions of economic slavery. Hitherto, the rule has been that during child-bearing age a woman must be supported by her husband, and the general feeling of the community has been opposed to any conditions likely to force married women on to the industrial market. In her own home a woman works hard, but she is working for the benefit of her family and not directly for the benefit of a stranger. If, instead of bearing children, women practise birth control, and if children are to be denied to the poor as a privilege of the rich, then it would be very easy to exploit the women of the poorer classes. If women have no young children why should they be exempt from the economic pressure that is applied to men? And indeed, where birth control is practised women tend more and more to supplant men, especially in ill-paid grades of work. One of the birth controllers has suggested that young couples, who otherwise could not afford to marry, should marry but have no children, and thus continue to work at their respective employments during the day. As the girl would have little time for cooking and other domestic duties, this immoralist is practically subverting the very idea of a home! The English poor have already lost even the meaning of the word “property,” and if the birth controllers had their way the meaning of the word “home” would soon follow. The aim of birth control is generally masked by falsehood, but the urging of this policy on the poor points unmistakably to the Servile State. When a nation, or a section of a nation, is oppressed, their birth-rate rises. That is the immutable law of nature as witnessed in history. Thus, the Israelites increased under the oppression of the Pharaohs. Thus, the Irish, from the Union to the Famine, multiplied prodigiously under the oppression of an iniquitous political and land system. By the operation of this law the oppressed grow in numbers, and break their chains.

    Section 7. A MENACE TO THE NATION

    (a) There is a Limit to lowering the Death-rate

    Birth controllers believe that a high birth-rate is the cause of a high death-rate, and that over-population is the cause of poverty. Yet, in spite of their beliefs, they make the following statement: “Neo-Malthusians have not aimed at reducing population, but only at reducing unnecessary death, which injures the community without adding to its numbers.” [80] In defence of this statement they argue that if the death-rate falls people will live longer, and therefore the population will not decrease, although the birth-rate is lowered. There are two fallacies in their argument. They overlook the fact that every one of us must die, and that therefore there is a limit beyond which a death-rate cannot possibly fall, whereas there is no limit, except zero, to the possible fall in a birth-rate. If a birth-rate fell to nothing and no children were born, it is obvious that the population would eventually vanish. The second fallacy is that a low birth-rate will permanently lower the death-rate. At first a falling birth-rate increases the proportion of young adults in the population, and, as the death-rate during early adult life is relatively low, the total death-rate tends to fall for a time. Sooner or later there is an increase in the proportion of old people in the population, and, as the death-rate during old age is high, the total death-rate tends to rise. That is now happening in England, and these are the actual facts as recorded by the Registrar-General:

        “It may be pointed out that, though the effect of the fall in the
        birth-rate has hitherto been an a sense advantageous in that it has
        increased the proportions living at the working ages, a tendency to the
        reversal of this fact has already set in, and may be expected to
        develop as time goes on....

        “The general characteristics of the figures indicate very clearly the
        effects of the long-continued decline in the birth-rate of this
        country, and show, by the example of France, the type of
        age-distribution which a further continuance of the decline is likely
        to produce. The present age-distribution of the English population is
        still favourable to low death-rates, but is becoming less so than it
        was in 1901. The movements along the curve of the point of maximum
        heaping up population, referred to on page 61 (See [Reference:
        Population]), has shifted this from age 20-25 to a period ten years
        later, when mortality is appreciably higher.”—Census of England and
        Wales, 1911. General Report, with Appendices, pp. 62 and 65.

    Of these facts the birth controllers, would appear to be ignorant. That is a charitable assumption; but, in view of the vital importance of this question their ignorance is culpable.

    (b) Birth Control tends to extinguish the Birth-rate

    Whatever may be the nebulous aim of birth controllers, the actual results of birth control are quite definite. We have no accurate information regarding the extent to which, birth control is practised, for, needless to say, the Malthusians can provide us with no exact figures bearing on this question; but we do know that birth control, when adopted, is mostly practised amongst the better paid artisans and wealthier classes. After full examination of the evidence; the National Birth-rate Commission were unanimously agreed “That the greater incidence of infant mortality upon the less prosperous classes does not reduce their effective fertility to the level of that of the wealthier classes.” [81] It is probable that this Commission overestimated the extent to which birth control has contributed to the declining birth-rate; but, even so, this does not alter the obvious fact that artificial birth control, when adopted, reduces fertility to a lower level than Nature intended. If language has any meaning, birth control means a falling birth-rate, and a falling birth-rate means depopulation. Here and there this evil practice may increase the material prosperity of an individual, but it lowers the prosperity of the nation by reducing the number of citizens. Moreover, as birth control is not a prevailing vice amongst semi-civilised peoples, the adoption of this practice by civilised nations means that the proportion of civilised to uncivilised inhabitants of the world will be reduced. If birth control had been extensively practised in the past the colonisation of the British Empire would have been a physical impossibility; and to-day, in our vast overseas dominions, are great empty spaces whose untilled soil and excellent climate await a population. Is that population to be white, or yellow? A question which to-day fills the Australian with apprehension.

    (c) A Danger to the Empire

    Many people are honestly perplexed by Neo-Malthusian propaganda, and are honestly ignorant of the truth concerning the population and the food supply of the British Empire. They think that if the population is increasing faster than the food supply, there is at least one argument in favour of artificial birth control from a practical, although possibly not from an ethical, point of view. They apply to that propaganda the ordinary test of the world, namely, 'Will it work?' rather than that other test which asks, 'Is it right?' The question I would put to people who reason in that way, and they are many, is a very simple one. If it can be proved that Neo-Malthusian propaganda is based on an absolute falsehood, will it not follow that the chief argument in favour of artificial birth control has been destroyed? Let us put this matter to the proof. Neo-Malthusians state that the population of the Empire is increasing more rapidly than the food supply. That is a definite statement. It is either true or false. To discover the truth, it is necessary to refer to the Memorandum of the Dominions Royal Commission, and it may be noted that publications of that sort are not usually read by the general public to whom the Neo-Malthusians appeal. The public are aware that the staff of life is made from wheat, but they are not aware of the following facts, which prove that in this matter, at any rate, Neo-Malthusian statements are absolutely false. In foreign countries the increase of the wheat area is proceeding at practically the same rate as the increase of population. Within the British Empire the wheat area is increasing more rabidly than the population.

    Between 1901 and 1911 the percentage increase of the wheat area was nearly seven times greater than the increase of population; and the percentage increase in the actual production of wheat was nearly twelve times greater than the increase of population. As these facts alone completely refute the Neo-Malthusian argument, it is advisable to reproduce here the official statistics. [82]

        “The requirements of wheat [83] for the United Kingdom and the extent
        to which Home and overseas supplies contributed towards these
        requirements during the period under review can be briefly summarised
        by the following table, viz.:

                         Normal Supplies Proportion of supply
        Annual requirements
        average Home Overseas Home Overseas

                         Million Million Million Per Per
                         cwts cwts cwts cent cent
        1901-5 138.8 28.7 110.1 20.7 79.3
        1906-10 143.2 31.9 111.3 22.3 77.7
        1911-13 149.2 32.9 116.3 22.1 77.9

        “The main sources of overseas supply are too well known to require
        recapitulation here. The imports from the Dominions and India and their
        proportionate contribution to the United Kingdom's total imports and
        wheat requirements since 1901 have been as follows:

                    1901-5
                         Percentage
         From Annual Total Total
                   average imports requirements

                   Million Per Per
                      cwts cent cent

         Canada 10.3 9.2 7.4
         Australia 6.6 5.9 4.8
         New Zealand .4 .4 .3
         India 15.5 13.9 11.2

                      32.8 29.4 23.7

                    1906-10
                         Percentage
         From Annual Total Total
                   average imports requirements

                   Million Per Per
                      cwts cent cent

         Canada 17.2 15.1 12.0
         Australia 9.4 8.2 6.6
         New Zealand .3 .3 .2
         India 13.3 11.7 9.3

                      32.8 29.4 23.7

                    1911-13
                         Percentage
         From Annual Total Total
                   average imports requirements

                   Million Per Per
                      cwts cent cent

         Canada 24.5 20.5 16.4
         Australia 12.6 10.6 8.4
         New Zealand .4 .3 .3
         India 21.5 18.0 14.4

                      59.0 49.4 39.5

        “The large increase in the proportion received from the Dominions is,
        of course, mainly due to the great extension of wheat cultivation in
        Western Canada since the beginning of the century.” [84]

        Future Supplies

        “As the United Kingdom is dependent for so large a proportion of its
        wheat supplies on the surplus of oversea countries, it is of material
        interest to examine whether this surplus is increasing, or whether the
        growth of population is proceeding more rapidly than the extension of
        the wheat-growing area.

        “The Board of Agriculture and Fisheries in 1912 estimated [85] that the
        extension of the wheat area and the growth of population during the
        period 1901-1911 was as follows:

                         Wheat area Percent Population. Percent
        Wheat-growing age in age in
        countries. 1901. 1911. crease 1901. 1911. crease

        British Empire Thousand Thousand Thousands Thousands
         (United Kingdom, acres. acres.
         Canada,
         Australia,
         New Zealand,
         and India). 34,696 50,490 +45.5 283,385 302,154 + 6.6
        European
          countries. 98,326 115,105 +17.1 291,685 337,181 +15.6
        Others 67,908 81,408 +19.9 139,927 168,818 +20.6

        “It is important to find that, while in foreign countries, both
        European and extra-European, the increase of wheat area is proceeding
        at practically the same rate as the increase of population, in the
        British Empire the wheat area is developing far more rapidly, so that
        the Empire as a whole is becoming more self-supporting.

        “The total production of wheat within the British Empire, which was
        227,500,000 cwts. in 1901, had risen to 399,700,000 cwts. in 1911, an
        increase of 75 per cent.

        “The relative yield per acre in 1911 was as follows:”

                         Yield per acre.

                         Average for five
                         years, 1906-10. 1911.
                         Bushels. Bushels.

        United Kingdom 32.88 32.96
        Canada 17.56[86] 20.80[87]
        Australia 11.74 9.65[88]
        New Zealand 28.72 36.73
        India
         (including Native States) 11.44 12.02

    The foregoing facts destroy the chief Neo-Malthusian argument, and, as birth control tends to extinguish the birth-rate, this Neo-Malthusian propaganda is a menace to the Empire. In fact, the danger is very great for the simple reason that the proportion of white people within the Empire is very small.

        “The British Empire's share of the world's people is very large, but it
        mainly consists, it should be remembered, of Asiatics and African
        natives. The Empire as a whole contains about 450 millions of the
        world's 1,800 millions, made up roundly as follows:

        United Kingdom 47,000,000
        Self-governing Dominions 22,000,000
        Rest of the Empire (chiefly India,
          319 millions) 378,000,000
        Total 447,000,000

        “Of the great aggregate Empire population of 447 millions, the white
        people account for no more than 65 millions. That is to say, outside
        the United Kingdom itself the Empire has only 18 million white people,
        or less than four million families. That figure, of course, includes
        Boers, French-Canadians, and others of foreign extraction. This fact is
        clearly not realized by those present-day Malthusians who assure us
        that too many Britons are being born.” [89]

    It is also well to remember that depopulation in Italy preceded the disintegration of the Roman Empire. Historians have estimated that, while under the Republic, Italy could raise an army of 800,000 men, under Titus that number was halved.

    Unfortunately there are some to whom this argument will not appeal, and wandering about in our midst are a few lost souls, so bemused by the doctrines of international finance that they see no virtue in patriotism or, in other words, in the love that a man has for his own home. They are unmoved by the story of sacrifice, of thrift, and of patient trust in God that is told for instance in the history of the Protestant manses of Scotland, where ministers on slender stipends brought up families of ten and twelve, where the boys won scholarships at the universities, and where women were the mothers of men.

    These days have been recalled by Norman Macleod:

        “The minister, like most of his brethren, soon took to himself a wife,
        the daughter of a neighbouring 'gentleman tacksman,' and the
        grand-daughter of a minister, well born and well bred; and never did
        man find a help more meet for him. In that manse they lived for nearly
        fifty years, and there were born to them sixteen children; yet neither
        father nor mother could ever lay hand on a child and say, 'We wish this
        one had not been.' They were all a source of unmingled joy....” [90]

        “A 'wise' neighbour once remarked, 'That minister with his large family
        will ruin himself, and if he dies they will be beggars.' Yet there has
        never been a beggar among then to the fourth generation.” [91]

    How did they manage to provide for their children? In this pagan, spoon-fed age, many people will laugh when they read the answer—in a family letter, written more than a hundred years ago by a man who was poor:

        “But the thought—I cannot provide for these! Take care, minister, the
        anxiety of your affection does not unhinge that confidence with which
        the Christian ought to repose upon the wise and good providence of
        God! What though you are to leave your children poor and friendless?
        Is the arm of the Lord shortened, that He cannot help? Is His ear
        heavy, that He cannot hear? You yourself have been no more than an
        instrument in the hand of His goodness; and is His goodness, pray,
        bound up in your feeble arm? Do you what you can; leave the rest to
        God. Let them be good, and fear the Lord, and keep His commandments,
        and He will provide for them in His own way and in His own time. Why,
        then, wilt thou be cast down, O my soul; why disquieted within me?
        Trust thou in the Lord! Under all the changes and the cares and the
        troubles of this life, may the consolations of religion support our
        spirits. In the multitude of thoughts within me, Thy comforts O my
        God, delight my soul! But no more of this preaching-like harangue, of
        which, I doubt not, you wish to be relieved. Let me rather reply to
        your letter, and tell you my news.” [92]

    That letter was written by Norman Macleod, ordained in 1774, and minister of the Church of Scotland in Morven for some forty years. His stipend was L40, afterwards raised to L80. He had a family of sixteen. One of his sons was minister in Campbelltown, and later in Glasgow. He had a family of eleven. His eldest son was Chaplain to Queen Victoria, and wrote the Reminiscences of a Highland Parish.

    The birth controllers ask why we should bring up children at great cost and trouble to ourselves, and they have been well answered by a non-Catholic writer, Dr. W.E. Home. [93]

        “One of my acquaintances refuses to have a second child because he
        could not then play golf. Is there, then, no pleasure in children which
        shall compensate for the troubles and expenses they bring upon you? I
        notice that the penurious Roman Catholic French Canadian farmers are
        spreading out of Quebec and occupying more and more of Ontario. I fancy
        these hard-living parents would think their struggles to bring up their
        large (ten to twenty) families worth while when they see how their
        group is strengthening its position. If a race comes to find no
        instinctive pleasure in children it will probably be swept away by
        others more virile. One man will live where another will starve;
        prudence and selfishness are not identical.

        “In her book, The Strength of a People, Mrs. Bosanquet, who signed
        the Majority Report of the Poor Law Commission, tells the story of two
        girls in domestic service who became engaged. One was imprudent,
        married at once, lived in lodgings, trusted to the Church and the
        parish doctor to see her through her first confinement, had no
        foresight or management, every succeeding child only added to her
        worries, and her marriage was a failure. The other was prudent, did not
        marry till, after six months, she and her fiance had chosen a house and
        its furniture. Then she married, and their house was their own careful
        choice; every table and chair reminded them of the afternoon they had
        had together when it was chosen; they were amusement enough to
        themselves, and they saved their money for the expenses of her
        confinement. He had not to seek amusement outside his home, did his
        work with a high sanction and got promoted, and each child was only an
        added pleasure. Idyllic; yes, but sometimes true. One of the happiest
        men I have known was a Marine sergeant with ten children, and a bed in
        his house for stray boys he thought he should help.

        “One of my friends married young and had five children; this required
        management. He certainly could not go trips, take courses and extra
        qualifications, but he did his work all right, and his sons were there
        to help in the war, and one of them has won a position of Imperial
        usefulness far above that of his father or me. Is that no compensation
        to his parents for old-time difficulties they have by now almost
        forgotten? A bad tree cannot bring forth good fruit.”

    Dr. W.E. Home is right, and the Neo-Malthusian golfer is wrong. Moreover, he is wrong as a golfer. Golf requires skill, a fine co-ordination of sight and touch, much patience and self-control: and many unfortunate people lack these qualities of mind and body, and are therefore unable to play this game with pleasure to themselves or to others. Consequently every golfer, no matter whether he accepts the hypothesis of Spencer or that of Weismann concerning the inheritance of acquired characteristics, should rejoice to see his large family in the links as a good omen for the future of this game, although there be some other reasons that also justify the existence of children.

    (d) The Dangers of Small Families

    In a Malthusian leaflet, written for the poor Dr. Binnie Dunlop states:

        “You must at least admit that there would be nothing like the usual
        poverty if married couples had only one child for every 20s. or so, a
        week of wages. Yet the population would continue to increase rapidly,
        because very few of the children of small families die or grow up
        weakly; and it would become stronger, richer, and of course much
        happier.” [94]

    The false suggestion contained in his first sentence, namely that a high birth-rate is the cause of poverty, has already been exposed (Chap. II), and apparently Dr. Binnie Dunlop has never considered why so many of the English people should be so poor as to enable him to make use of their very poverty in order to tempt them to adopt an evil method of birth control. Moreover, his second contention, that a small family produces a higher type of child, better fed, better trained, and healthier, than is found amongst the children of large families is contrary to the following facts, as stated by Professor Meyrick Booth:

        “1. A civilisation cannot be maintained with an average of less than
        about four children per marriage; a smaller number will lead to actual
        extinction.

        “2. Much information exists tending to show that heredity strongly
        favours the third, fourth, fifth, and subsequent children born to a
        given couple, rather than the first two, who are peculiarly apt to
        inherit some of the commonest physical and mental defects (upon this
        important point the records of the University of London Eugenics
        Laboratory should be consulted). A population with a low birth-rate
        thus naturally tends to degenerate. It is the normal, and not the
        small family, that gives the best children
    .

        “3. The present differential birth-rate—high amongst the less
        intelligent classes and low amongst the most capable families—so far
        from leading upwards, is causing the race to breed to a lower type.

        “4. The small family encourages the growth of luxury and the
        development of what M. Leroy-Beaulieu calls l'esprit arriviste.

        “5. The popular idea that childbirth is injurious to a woman's health
        is probably quite erroneous. Where the birth-rate is high the health
        of the woman is apparently better
    than where it is artificially low.

        “6. A study of history does not show that nations with low birth-rates
        have been able to attain to a higher level of civilisation. Such
        nations have been thrust into the background by their hardier
        neighbours.” [95]

    Moreover, M. Leroy-Beaulieu, in La Question de la Population [96] states that those districts of France which show an exceptionally low birthrate are distinguished by a peculiar atmosphere of materialism, and that their inhabitants exhibit, in a high degree, an attitude of mind well named l'esprit arriviste—the desire to concentrate on outward success, to push on, to be climbers, to advance themselves and their children in fashionable society. This spirit means the willing sacrifice of all ideals of ethics or of patriotism to family egoism. To this mental attitude, and to the corresponding absence of religion, he attributes the decline of population. In conclusion the following evidence is quoted by Professor Meyrick Booth:

        “The Revue des Deux Mondes for July 1911 contains a valuable account,
        by a doctor resident in Gascony, of the state of things in that part of
        France (where, it will be remembered, the birth-rate is especially
        low). He expresses with the utmost emphasis the conviction that the
        Gascons are deteriorating, physically and mentally, and points out, at
        the same time, that the decline of population has had an injurious
        effect upon the economic condition of the country. 'L'hyponatalite est
        une cause precise et directe de la degenerescence de la race,' he
        writes. And, dealing with the belief that a low birthrate will result
        in the development of a superior type of child, he says: 'C'est une
        illusion qui ne resiste pas a la lumiere des faits tels que les montre
        l'etude demographique de nos villages gascons. Depuis que beaucoup de
        bancs restent vides a la petite ecole, les ecoliers ne sont ni mieux
        doues, ni plus travailleurs, et ils sont certainement moins vigoureux.'
        And again, 'La quantite est en general la condition premiere et
        souveraine de la qualite.'“ [97]

    Section 8. THE PLOT AGAINST CHRISTENDOM

    All purposive actions are ultimately based on philosophy of one sort or another. If, for example, we find a rich man founding hospitals for the poor, we may assume that he believes in the principle of Charity. It is, therefore, of prime importance to determine what kind of philosophy underlies Neo-Malthusian propaganda. The birth controllers profess to be actuated solely by feelings of compassion and of benevolence towards suffering humanity; and it is on these grounds that they are appealing to the Church of England to bless their work, or at least to lend to their propaganda a cloak of respectability. Now, the very fact that Neo-Malthusians are sincere in their mistaken and dangerous convictions makes it all the more necessary that we should discover the doctrines on which their propaganda was originally based; because, although their economic fallacies were borrowed from Malthus, their philosophy came from a different source.

    This philosophy is to be found, naked and unashamed, in a book entitled The Elements of Social Science. I have already referred to this work as the Bible of Neo-Malthusians, and its teaching has been endorsed as recently as 1905 by the official journal of the Malthusian League, as witness the following eulogy, whose last lines recall the happy days of Bret Harte in the Far West, and the eloquent periods of our old and valued friend Colonel Starbottle:

        “This work should be read by all followers of J.S. Mill, Garnier, and
        the Neo-Malthusian school of economists. We could give a long criticism
        of the many important chapters in this book; but, as we might be
        considered as prejudiced in its favour because of our agreement with
        its aims, we prefer to cite the opinion given by the editor of that
        widely circulated and most enlightened paper The Weekly Times and
        Echo
    , which appears in its issue of October 8.” [98]

    Before quoting from the book an explanation is due to my readers. I do not suggest that all of those who are to-day supporting the propaganda for artificial birth control would agree with its foolish blasphemies and drivelling imbecilities; but it is nevertheless necessary to quote these things, because our birth controllers are too wise in their day and generation to reveal to the public, still less to the Church of England, the philosophy on which Neo-Malthusianism was originally based, and from which it has grown. Moreover, the Malthusians claim that it was the author of the Elements of Social Science “who interested Mr. Charles Bradlaugh and Mrs. Annie Besant in the question.” [99] Four quotations from the last edition of the book will suffice:

        “But this is a certain truth, that any human being, any one of us,
        no matter how fallen and degraded, is an infinitely more glorious
        and adorable being than any God that ever was or will be
        conceived” (p. 413).

    In justice to the memory of John Stuart Mill, whom Malthusians are ever quoting, it should be noted that the foregoing blasphemy is nothing more nor less than a burlesque of Positivism or of Agnosticism. The teaching of Mill, Bain, and of Herbert Spencer was that the knowledge of God and of His nature is impossible, because our senses are the only source of knowledge. Their reasoning was wrong—because a primary condition of all knowledge is memory, in itself an intuition, because primary mathematical axioms are intellectual intuitions, and because mind has the power of abstraction; but, even so, not one of these men was capable of having written the above-quoted passage. The next quotation refers to marriage.

        “Marriage is based upon the idea that constant and unvarying love is
        the only one which is pure and honourable, and which should be
        recognised as morally good. But there could not be a greater error than
        this. Love is, like all other human passions and appetites, subject to
        change, deriving a great part of its force and continuance from variety
        in its objects; and to attempt to fix it to an invariable channel is to
        try to alter the laws of its nature"(p. 353).

    That quotation is an example of how evil ideas may arise from muddled thinking: because if the word “lust” be substituted for the word “love” in the third sentence, the remaining forty-five words would merely convey a simple truth, expressed by Kipling in two lines:

        “For the more you 'ave known o' the others
        The less will you settle to one.”

    Very few people, I suppose, are so foolish as to believe that man is by nature either a chaste or a constant animal, and indeed in this respect he appears to his disadvantage when compared with certain varieties of birds, which are by nature constant to each other. On the other hand, millions of people believe that man is able to overcome his animal nature; and for the past two thousand years the civilised races of the world have held that this is a goal towards which mankind should strive. In the opinion of Christendom chastity and marriage are both morally good, but, according to the philosophy of our Neo-Malthusian author, they are morally evil.

        “Chastity, or complete sexual abstinence, so far from being a virtue,
        is invariably a great natural sin” (p. 162).

    Is it not obvious that to the writers of such passages love is synonymous with animalism, with lust? It is by no means necessary to go to saints or to moralists for a refutation of this Neo-Malthusian philosophy. Does any decent ordinary man or woman agree with it? Ask the man in the street. Turn the pages of our literature. Refer to Chaucer or Spenser, to Shakespeare or Milton, refer to Fielding or Burns or Scott or Tennyson. Some of these men were very imperfect; but they all knew the difference between lust and love; and it is because they can tell us at least something of that which is precious, enduring, ethereal, and divine in love that we read their pages and honour their names. Not one of these men could have written the following sentence:

                “Marriage distracts our attention from the real sexual
                duties, and this is one of its worst effects” (p. 366).

    Now it is certain that if “the real sexual duties” are represented by promiscuous fornication, then both marriage and chastity are evil things. That philosophy is very old. From time immemorial—it has been advocated by one of the most powerful intelligences in the universe. Such is the soil on which the Neo-Malthusian fungus has grown—a soil that would rot the foundations of Europe.

    [Footnote 66: The Lancet, May 14, 1921, p. 1024]

    [Footnote 67: British Medical Journal, 1921, vol. ii, p. 93.]

    [Footnote 68: The Small Family System, 2nd edit., p. 2.]

    [Footnote 69: Supplement to The British Medical Journal, March 18, 1905, p. 110.]

    [Footnote 70: Common Sense on the Population Question, by Teresa Billington-Greig, p. 4. Published by the Malthusian League.]

    [Footnote 71: Medico-Legal Society, July 7, 1921.]

    [Footnote 72: Suppl. Qu. 49, Art. 6: “Voluptates meretricias vir in uxore quoerit quando nihil aliud in ea attendit quam quod in meretrice attenderet” (A husband seeks from his wife harlot pleasures when he asks from her only what he might ask from a harlot). Quoted by the Rev. Vincent McNabb, O.P., The Catholic Gazette, September 1921, p. 195.]

    [Footnote 73: British Medical Journal, 1921, vol. ii, p. 169.]

    [Footnote 74: Reproduced in fourth edition, 1861.]

    [Footnote 75: Essays in Medical Sociology, 1899. Revised and printed for private circulation, p. 95, (Copy in Library of Royal Society of Medicine).]

    [Footnote 76: British Medical Journal, August 20, 1921, p. 302.]

    [Footnote 77: St. Matt. xviii. 6.]

    [Footnote 78: Proceedings of the Medico-Legal Society, July 7, 1921]

    [Footnote 79: “That arrangement of society in which so considerable a number of the families and individuals are constrained by positive law to labour for the advantage of other families and individuals as to stamp the whole community with the mark of such labour we call The Servile State.”—Hilaire Belloc, The Servile State, 1912, p. 16.]

    [Footnote 80: The Secretary of the Malthusian League. Vide The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 89.]

    [Footnote 81: The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 37.]

    [Footnote 82: Dominions Royal Commission, Memorandum and Tables relating to the Food and Raw Material Requirements of the United Kingdom: prepared by the Royal Commission on the Natural Resources, Trade, and Legislation of Certain Portions of His Majesty's Dominions. November, 1915, pp. 1 and 2. My italics—H.G.S.]

    [Footnote 83: i.e. grain, wheatmeal, and flour]

    [Footnote 84: For particulars of this increase see Canada Year Book 1913, p. 144.]

    [Footnote 85: See pp. 387-8 of [Cd. 6588].]

    [Footnote 86: Average for period 1907-1910 and excluding British Columbia, where the yield per acre in 1911, the only year for which figures are available, averaged 29-37 bushels.]

    [Footnote 87: Including British Columbia.]

    [Footnote 88: Below the average. The yield per acre in 1912 was 12.53 bushels, and in 1913 11.18.]

    [Footnote 89: The Observer, Nov. 11, 1921.]

    [Footnote 90: Reminiscences of a Highland Parish, by Norman Macleod, D.D., 1876, p. 27.]

    [Footnote 91: Ibid., p. 34.]

    [Footnote 92: Ibid., p. 91.]

    [Footnote 93: British Medical Journal, August 13, 1921, p. 261.]

    [Footnote 94: Leaflet of the Malthusian League.]

    [Footnote 95: The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, p. 153. My italics.—H.G.S.]

    [Footnote 96: Quoted by Professor Meyrick Booth, The Hibbert Journal, October 1914, p. 153.]

    [Footnote 97: The Hibbert Journal, October 1914.]

    [Footnote 98: The Malthusian, November 1905, p. 84]

    [Footnote 99: C.V. Drysdale, O.B.E., D. Sc., The Small Family System, 1918, p. 150.]

    CHAPTER VIII. THE RELIGIOUS ARGUMENT AGAINST BIRTH CONTROL

    Section 1. AN OFFENCE AGAINST THE LAW OF NATURE

    Birth control is against the law of nature, which Christians believe to be the reflection of the divine law in human affairs, and any violation of this law was held to be vicious even by the ancient pagan world. To this argument an advocate of birth control has made answer:

        “We interfere with nature at every point—we shave, cut our hair, cook
        our food, fill cavities in our teeth (or wear artificial teeth), clothe
        ourselves, wear boots, hats, and wash our faces, so why should birth
        alone be sacred from the touch and play of human moulding?” [100]

    Why? For a very simple reason. Birth control belongs to the moral sphere; it essentially affects man's progress in good, whereas all the other things that he mentions have no more moral significance than has the practice of agriculture. Regarded in the light of the law of nature they are neutral actions, neither good nor bad in themselves, raising no question of right or wrong, and having no real bearing on the accomplishment of human destiny. To make no distinction between the merely physical law of nature (expressed in the invariable tendency of everything to act according to its kind) and the natural moral law which governs human conduct, is to pronounce oneself a materialist. Yet even a materialist ought to denounce the practice of birth control, as it violates the laws of nature which regulate physical well-being. “But,” says the materialist, “it is not possible for anyone to act against nature, because all actions take place in nature, and therefore every act is a natural act.” Quite so: in that sense murder is a natural act; even unnatural vice is a natural act. Will any one defend them? There is a natural law in the physical world, and there is a natural law in conscience—a law of right conduct. Certain actions are under the control of the human will, which is able to rebel against the moral law of nature, and the pagan poet Aeschylus traces all human sorrow to “the perverse human will omnipresent.”

    As birth control means the deliberate frustration of a natural act which might have issued in a new life, it is an unnatural crime, and is stigmatised by theologians as a sin akin to murder. To this charge birth controllers further reply that millions of the elements of procreation are destroyed by Nature herself, and that “to add one more to these millions sacrificed by Nature is surely no crime.” This attempt at argument is pathetic. If these people knew even the A.B.C. of biology, they would know that millions of those elements are allowed to perish by Nature for a definite purpose—namely, to make procreation more certain. It is in order that the one may achieve the desired end that it is reinforced by millions of others. Moreover, although millions of deaths in the world occur every year from natural causes, it would nevertheless, I fear, be a crime if I were to cause one more death by murdering a birth controller.

    Section 2. REFLECTED IN THE NORMAL CONSCIENCE

    In common with irrational animals we have instincts, appetites, and passions; but, unlike the animals, we have the power to reflect whether an action is right or wrong in itself apart from its consequences. This power of moral judgment is called conscience; and it is conscience which reflects the natural law (the Divine Nature expressed in creation). As conscience, when violated, can and does give rise to an unpleasant feeling of shame in the mind, we have good reason to believe that it exists for the purpose of preventing us from doing shameful actions, just as our eyes are intended, amongst other things, to prevent us from walking over precipices. Moreover, if the conscience is active, instructed, and unbiassed, it will invariably give the correct answer to any question of right or wrong.

    It is possible to assert, without fear of contradiction, that no ordinary decent man or woman approaches or begins the practice of artificial birth control without experiencing at first unpleasant feelings of uneasiness, hesitation, repugnance, shame, and remorse. Later on these feelings may be overcome by habit, for the voice of conscience will cease when it has been frequently ignored. This does not alter the fact that at first the natural moral instincts of both men and women do revolt against these practices. To the conscience of mankind birth control is a shameful action.

    Section 3. EXPRESSED IN THE SCIENCE OF ETHICS

    The dictates of conscience go to form the science of ethics. According to ethics, the practice of birth control means the doing of an act whilst at the same time frustrating the object for which the act is intended. It is like using language to conceal the truth, or using appetite so as to injure rather than to promote health. During the decline of the Roman Empire men gorged themselves with food, took an emetic, vomited, and then sat down to eat again. They satiated their appetite and frustrated the object for which appetite is intended. The practice of birth control is parallel to this piggishness. No one can deny that the sexual impulse has for aim the procreation of children. The birth controllers seek to gratify the impulse, yet to defeat the aim; and they are so honest in their mistaken convictions that, when faced with this argument, they boldly adopt an attitude which spells intellectual and moral anarchy. They say that it is simply a waste of time to discuss the moral aspect of this practice. Without being able to dispute the truth that birth control is against nature, conscience, and ethics, they attempt to prove that at any rate the results of this practice are beneficial, or in other words that a good end justifies the use of evil means. This is a doctrine that has been universally repudiated by mankind. [101] Nevertheless, if birth control, in spite of its being an offence against moral and natural law, was really beneficial to humanity, then birth controllers would be able to claim pragmatic justification for the practices, and to argue that what actually and universally tends to the good of mankind cannot be bad in itself. Birth control, as I have already shown, does not conform to these conditions; therefore that argument also fails.

    Section 4. BIRTH CONTROL CONDEMNED BY PROTESTANT CHURCHES

    The Protestants, at the time of the Reformation, retained and even exaggerated certain beliefs of the undivided Catholic Church. None of them doubted, for instance, that the Bible was the Word of God and therefore a guide to moral conduct. They knew that artificial birth control is forbidden by the Bible, and that in the Old Testament the punishment for that sin was death. [102] In 1876, when Charles Bradlaugh advocated in a notorious pamphlet the practice of birth control, his views were denounced from every Protestant pulpit in the land, and were widely repudiated by the upper and middle classes of England. But it would seem that Protestant morality is now disappearing with the spread of indifferentism, and the Protestant Churches have no longer the same influence on the public and private life of the nation. Protestantism has lasted for 400 years, but though it has lasted longer than any other form of belief which took rise in the sixteenth century, it is now also dying.

    In 1919 the number of people over seven years of age in England who professed belief in any church was 10,833,795 (out of 40,000,000), and the church attendance equalled 7,000,000, or about 1 out of every 5 people. [103]

    Again, a Commission appointed by the Protestant Churches to inquire into the religious beliefs held in the British armies of the Great War has endorsed the following statements:

        “Everyone must be struck with the appalling ignorance of the simplest
        religious truths. Probably 80 per cent, of these men from the Midlands
        had never heard of the sacraments.... It is not only that the men do
        not know the meaning of 'Church of England'; they are ignorant of the
        historical facts of the life of our Lord. Nor must it be assumed that
        this ignorance is confined to men who have passed through the
        elementary schools. The same verdict is recorded upon those who have
        been educated in our public schools.... The men are hopelessly
        perplexed by the lack of Christian unity.” [104]

    In my opinion these statements are exaggerations, but that was not the view of the Commission. As regards Scotland, it has recently been stated at the Lothian Synod of the United Free Church that in 1911 at least 37 per cent. of the men and women of Scotland were without church connection. [105]

    In 1870, of every 1,000 marriages, 760 were according to the rites of the Established Church, but in 1919 the proportion had fallen to 597. During the same period civil marriages without religious ceremonial increased from 98 to 231 per 1,000. [106] These figures are an index of the religious complexion of the country. The Protestant Churches are being strangled by the development of a germ that was inherent in them from the beginning, and that growth is Rationalism. The majority of the upper, professional, and artisan class can no longer be claimed as staunch Protestants, but as vague theists; and amongst these educated people, misled by false ideas of pleasure and by pernicious nonsense written about self-realisation, the practice of birth control has spread most alarmingly. This is an evil against which all religious bodies who retain a belief in the fundamental facts of Christianity might surely unite in action.

    In a Catholic country there would be no need, in the furtherance of public welfare, to write on the evils of birth control. The teaching of the Catholic Church would be generally accepted, and a moral law generally accepted by the inhabitants of a country gives strength to the State. But Great Britain, no longer Catholic, is now in some danger of ceasing to be even a Christian country. In 1885 it was asserted, “England alone is reported to contain some seven hundred sects, each of whom proves a whole system of theology and morals from the Bible.” [107] Each of these that now survives gives its own particular explanation of the law of God, which it honestly tries to follow, but at one point or another each and every sect differs from its neighbours. On account of these differences of opinion many people say: “The Churches cannot agree amongst themselves as to what is truth; they cannot all be right; it is, therefore, impossible for me to know with certainty what to believe; and, to be quite honest, it may save me a lot of bother just at present to have no very firm belief at all.” This means that in Great Britain there is no uniform moral law covering all human conduct and generally accepted by the mass of the people. As the practice of artificial birth-rate control is not only contrary to Christian morality, but is also a menace to the prosperity and well-being of the nation, the absence of a uniform moral law, common to all the people and forbidding this practice, is a source of grave weakness in the State.

    APPENDIX TO CHAPTER VIII

    A NEO-MALTHUSIAN ATTACK ON THE CHURCH OF ENGLAND

    As was proved in a previous chapter (p. 120) artificial birth control was originally based on Atheism, and on a philosophy of moral anarchy. Further proof of this fact is to be found in the course of a most edifying dispute between two rival Neo-Malthusians. This quarrel is between Dr. Marie C. Stopes, President of the Society for Constructive Birth Control and Racial Progress, who is not a Doctor of Medicine but of Philosophy, and Dr. Binnie Dunlop, who is a Bachelor of Medicine: and when birth controllers fall out we may humbly hope that truth will prevail. Dr. Stopes maintains that artificial birth control was not an atheistic movement, whereas Dr. Binnie Dunlop contends that the pioneers of the movement were Atheists. The beginning of the trouble was a letter written by Dr. Stopes to the British Medical Journal, in which she made the following statement:

        “Dr. Martindale is reported in your pages to have given an address to
        medical women in which she pointed out that the birth control movement
        in England dated from the Bradlaugh trial in 1877. Had she attended the
        presidential address of the Society for Constructive Birth Control she
        would have learned that there was a very flourishing movement, centring
        round Dr. Trall in 1866, years before Bradlaugh touched the subject,
        and also a considerable movement earlier than that. This point is
        important, as 'birth control' has hitherto (erroneously) been much
        prejudiced in popular opinion by being supposed to be an atheistical
        movement originated by Bradlaugh.” [108]

    Dr. Stopes, who has been working overtime in the attempt to obtain some religious sanction for her propaganda, is ready not only to throw the Atheists overboard, but also to assert that a flourishing movement for artificial birth control centred round the late Dr. Trall, who was a Christian. Her letter was answered by Dr. Binnie Dunlop as follows:

        “Dr. Marie C. Stopes, whose valuable books I constantly recommend,
        protests (page 872) against the statement that the birth control
        movement in England dated from the trial of Charles Bradlaugh in
        1877—for re-publishing Dr. Knowlton's pamphlet, The Fruits of
        Philosophy
    because the Government had interdicted it. She must admit,
        however, that there was no organised movement anywhere until
        Bradlaugh and the Doctors Drysdale, immediately after the trial,
        founded the Malthusian League, and that the decline of Europe's
        birthrate began in that year. It may now seem unfortunate that the
        pioneers of the contraceptives idea, from 1818 onwards (James Mill,
        Francis Place, Richard Carlile, Robert Dale Owen, John Stuart Mill, Dr.
        Knowlton, Dr. George Drysdale, Dr. C.R. Drysdale, and Charles
        Bradlaugh), were all Free-thinkers; and Dr. Stopes harps on the
        religious and praiseworthy Dr. Trall, an American, who published
        Sexual Physiology in 1866. But Dr. Trall was not at all a strong
        advocate of contraceptive methods. After a brief but helpful reference
        to the idea of placing a mechanical obstruction, such as a sponge,
        against the os uteri, he said:

        “Let it be distinctly understood that I do not approve any method for
        preventing pregnancy except that of abstinence, nor any means for
        producing abortion, on the ground that it is or can be in any sense
        physiological. It is only the least of two evils. When people will live
        physiologically there will be no need of preventive measures, nor will
        there be any need for works of this kind.” [109]

    That is a most informative letter. In simple language Dr. Binnie Dunlop tells the remarkable story of how in 1876 three Atheists, merely by forming a little Society in London, were able to cause an immediate fall in the birth-rate of Europe. When you come to think of it, that was a stupendous thing for any three men to have achieved. I am very glad that Dr. Binnie Dunlop has defended the Atheists and has painted the late Dr. Trail, despite that “brief but helpful reference,” in his true colours as a Christian. Nevertheless, Dr. Stopes had the last word:

        “As regards Dr. Dunlop, he now shifts the Atheists' position by adding
        the word 'organised.' The Atheists never tire of repeating certain
        definite misstatements, examples of which are: 'If it were not for the
        fact that the despised Atheists, Charles Bradlaugh and Annie Besant,
        faced imprisonment, misrepresentation, insult, and ostracism for this
        cause forty-four years ago, she [Dr. Stopes] would not be able to
        conduct her campaign to-day' (Literary Guide, November, 1921); and
        'Before the Knowlton trial, neither rich nor poor knew anything worth
        counting about contraceptive devices' (Malthusian, November 15,
        1921). Variations of these statements have been incessantly made, and I
        dealt with their contentions in the presidential address for the C.B.C.
        Meanwhile to them I reply that: 'There has never been in this country
        any law against the dissemination of properly presented birth control
        information, and before, during, and after the Bradlaugh trial
        properly presented information on birth control was extending its range
        with full liberty.' My address is now in the press, and when published
        will make public not only new matter from manuscript letters of very
        early date in my possession, but other overlooked historical facts. I
        have already told Dr. Dunlop I refuse to be drawn into a discussion on
        facts an account of which is still in the press.” [110]

    The lady, by her dissertation on the Laws of England, makes a clumsy effort to evade the point at issue, which is quite simple, namely, whether it was Atheists or Christians who initiated the Neo-Malthusian movement, organised or unorganised. Dr. Binnie Dunlop has here proved his case. I also do maintain that in this matter all credit must be given to the Atheists; and that it would be truly contemptible to deny this fact merely in order to pander to a popular prejudice against Atheism. Nor am I shaken in this opinion when Dr. Stopes points out that there was a Neo-Malthusian movement prior to 1876. Of course there was a movement, but it was always an atheistic movement. In the past no Christian doctor, and indeed no Christian man or woman, advocated artificial birth control. Let us give the Neo-Malthusian his due.

    Until recently both the Church of England and the medical profession presented practically a united front against Neo-Malthusian teaching; and, as late as 1914, the Malthusian League did not hesitate to make use of the following calumnies, very mean, very spiteful, very imbecile:

        “Take the clergy. They are the officers of a Church that has made
        marriage a source of revenue and of social control; they preach from a
        sacred book that bids the chosen people of God 'multiply and replenish
        the earth'; they know that large families generally tend to preserve
        clerical influence and authority; and they claim that every baby is a
        new soul presented to God and, therefore, for His honour and glory, the
        greatest possible number of souls should be produced.” [111]

    That feeble attempt to poison the atmosphere was naturally ignored by intelligent people; and more than once Lambeth has ruled that artificial birth control is sin. Unfortunately, within the Church of England, in spite of the Lambeth ruling, there is still discussion as to whether artificial birth control is or is not sin, the Bishops, as a whole, making a loyal effort to uphold Christian teaching against a campaign waged by Malthusians in order to obtain religious sanction for their evil propaganda. Although many Malthusians are rationalists, they are well aware that without some religious sanction their policy could never emerge from the dim underworld of unmentioned and unrespected things, and could never be advocated openly in the light of day. To this end birth control is camouflaged by pseudo-poetic and pseudo-religious phraseology, and the Anglican Church is asked to alter her teaching. Birth controllers realise that it is useless to ask this of the Catholic Church, a Rock in their path, but “as regards the Church of England, which makes no claim to infallibility, the case is different, and discussion is possible.” [112]

    Let us consider, firstly, the teaching of the Church of England on this matter. At the Lambeth Conference of 1908 the Bishops affirmed “that deliberate tampering with nascent life is repugnant to Christian morality.” In 1914 a Committee of Bishops issued a Memorandum [113] in which artificial birth control is condemned as “dangerous, demoralising, and sinful.” The memorandum was approved by a large majority of the Diocesan Bishops, although in the opinion of Dean Inge “this is emphatically a matter in which every man and woman must judge for themselves, and must refrain from judging others.” [114] The Bishops also held that in some marriages it may be desirable, on grounds of prudence or of health, to limit the number of children. In these circumstances they advised the practice of self-restraint; and, as regards a limited use of marriage, they added the following statement:

        “It seems to most of us only a legitimate application of such
        self-restraint that in certain cases (which only the parties' own
        judgment and conscience can settle) intercourse should be restricted by
        consent to certain times at which it is less likely to lead to
        conception. This is only to use natural conditions; it is approved by
        good medical authority; it means self-denial and not self-indulgence.
        And we believe it to be quite legitimate, or at least not to be
        condemned.”

    A small minority of Bishops held that prolonged or even perpetual abstinence from intercourse is the only legitimate method of limiting a family. Finally, in Resolution 68 of the Lambeth Conference in 1920, the Bishops stated that:

        “We utter an emphatic warning against the use of unnatural means for
        the avoidance of conception, together with the grave
        dangers—physical, moral, and religious—thereby incurred, and against
        the evils with which the extension of such use threatens the race. In
        opposition to the teaching which, under the name of science and
        religion, encourages married people in the deliberate cultivation of
        sexual union as an end in itself, we steadfastly uphold what must
        always be regarded as the governing consideration of Christian
        marriage. One is the primary purpose for which marriage
        exists—namely, the continuation of the race through the gift and
        heritage of children; the other is the paramount importance in married
        life of deliberate and thoughtful self-control.” [115]

    And the Committee on “Problems of Marriage and Sexual Morality” felt called upon “to utter an earnest warning against the use of any unnatural means by which conception is frustrated.” [116]

    If Resolution 68 be read in conjunction with the Memorandum of 1914, the teaching of the Church of England is plain to any sane man or woman; it is one with the teaching of the Church Catholic. Artificial birth control is condemned as sin, but, under certain circumstances, the limitation of a family by continence or by restricted intercourse is permitted. As this teaching forbids Neo-Malthusian practices, birth controllers have tried to make the Church alter her teaching to suit their opinions. Although their methods in controversy against the Church must be condemned by everyone who values intellectual honesty, the reader, of his charity, should remember that Malthusians are unable to defend their policy, either on logical or on moral grounds. Without attempting to prove that the teaching of the Church is wrong, birth controllers began the attack by a complete misrepresentation of what that teaching actually is. This unenviable task was undertaken by Lord Dawson of Penn, at the Birmingham Church Congress of 1921.

    After quoting Resolution 68, Lord Dawson said:

        “Now the plain meaning of this statement is that sexual union should
        take place for the sole purpose of procreation, that sexual union as
        an end in itself—not, mind you, the only end—(there we should all
        agree), but sexual union as an end in itself is to be condemned.

        “That means that sexual intercourse should rightly take place only
        for the purpose of procreation.

        “Quite a large family could easily result from quite a few sexual
        unions. For the rest the couple should be celibate. Any intercourse not
        having procreation as its intention is 'sexual union as an end in
        itself,' and therefore by inference condemned by the Lambeth
        Conference.

        “Think of the facts of life. Let us recall our own love—our marriage,
        our honeymoon. Has not sexual union over and over again been the
        physical expression of our love without thought or intention of
        procreation? Have we all been wrong? Or is it that the Church lacks
        that vital contact with the realities of life which accounts for the
        gulf between her and the people?

        “The love envisaged by the Lambeth Conference is an invertebrate,
        joyless thing—not worth the having. Fortunately it is in contrast to
        the real thing as practised by clergy and laity.

        “Fancy an ardent lover (and what respect have you for a lover who is
        not ardent?)—the type you would like your daughter to marry—virile,
        ambitious, chivalrous—a man who means to work hard and love hard.
        Fancy putting before these lovers—eager and expectant of the joys
        before them—the Lambeth picture of marriage. Do you expect to gain
        their confidence?” [117]

    That sort of appeal is not very effective, even as rhetoric; but it is very easy to give an exact parallel. Fancy a fond father (and what respect have you for a father who is not fond?) being told by his daughter's suitor that he, his prospective son-in-law, looked forward to the physical joys of marriage, but intended to insist on his wife using contraceptives. Would any father regard such a one as the type he would like his daughter to marry?

    There is, unfortunately, another answer to Lord Dawson, and I put it in the form of a question. Can any intelligent man or woman, Catholic, Protestant, or rationalist, maintain that Lord Dawson has given a fair, a true, or an honest statement of the teaching of the Church of England? Moreover, it is past all understanding how a gross libel on Anglican doctrine has been overlooked by those most concerned. The address is actually hailed as “wise, bold, and humane in the highest sense of the word” by The Spectator, [118] and that amazing journal, “expert as ever in making the worse appear the better cause in a way that appeals to clergymen,” goes on to say: “Lord Dawson fearlessly and plainly opposed the teachings of the Roman Church and the alleged teachings of the Anglican.”

    Having by a travesty of truth created a false theological bogey, bearing little resemblance either to Catholic or to Anglican teaching, Lord Dawson proceeds to demolish his own creation by a somewhat boisterous eulogy of sex-love. Now sex-love is an instinct and involves no question of good or evil apart from the circumstances in which it is either gratified or denied; but, in view of the freedom with which Lord Dawson discussed this topic, it is only right to note that it was left to the Rev. R.J. Campbell to add to the gaiety of nations by his subsequent protest that the Marriage Service “contains expressions which are offensive to modern delicacy of feeling.”

    That protest is also a first-rate example of the anarchical state of the modern mind. The Rev. R.J. Campbell is a modern mind, so is Mr. George Bernard Shaw; but the latter refers to “the sober decency, earnestness, and authority” [119] of those very passages to which the former objects.

    Lord Dawson's eulogy of sexual intercourse was but a prelude to his plea for the use of contraceptives:

        “I will next consider Artificial Control. The forces in modern life
        which make for birth control are so strong that only convincing reasons
        will make people desist from it. It is said to be unnatural and
        intrinsically immoral. This word 'unnatural' perplexes me. Why?
        Civilisation involves the chaining of natural forces and their
        conversion to man's will and uses. Much of medicine and surgery
        consists of means to overcome nature.”

    That paragraph illustrates precisely the confused use of the word “natural,” which I have already criticised (p. 124). Lord Dawson says he is perplexed, and I agree with him. Civilisation, he says, involves the conversion of natural forces to man's will. So does every crime. Is that any defence of crime? Even if physical nature be described as non-moral, that description cannot be applied to the inward nature of will and conscience. That I will an act may show it is in accordance with nature in a certain sense, but the fact of its being in accordance with physical nature does not justify my act. Does Lord Dawson agree? Or does he think that any action in accordance with the physical laws of nature, which means any action whatsoever, is justified; and does he approve therefore of mere moral anarchy? His confusion of thought concerning the use of the word “natural” is followed by the inevitable sequence of false analogies:

        “When anaesthetics were first used at child-birth there was an outcry
        on the part of many worthy and religious people that their use under
        such circumstances was unnatural and wicked, because God meant woman to
        suffer the struggles and pains of child-birth. Now we all admit it is
        right to control the process of child-birth, and to save the mother as
        much pain as possible. It is no more unnatural to control conception by
        artificial means than to control child-birth by artificial means.
        Surely the whole question turns on whether these artificial means are
        for the good or harm of the individual and the community.

        “Generally speaking, birth control before the first child is
        inadvisable. On the other hand, the justifiable use of birth control
        would seem to be to limit the number of children when such is
        desirable, and to spread out their arrival in such a way as to serve
        their true interests and those of their home.

        “Once more, careful distinction needs to be made between the use and
        the bad effects of the abuse of birth control. That its abuse produces
        grave harm I fully agree—harm to parents, to families, and to the
        nation. But abuse is not a just condemnation of legitimate use.
        Over-eating, over-drinking, over-smoking, over-sleeping, over-work do
        not carry condemnation of eating, drinking, smoking, sleeping, work.”

    These long extracts are here quoted because, as The Spectator has remarked, “an attempt at a detailed summary might destroy the careful balance which is essential to Lord Dawson's purpose.” It might indeed; and many a true word is written inadvertently and despite the wisdom of the serpent. As Lord Dawson believes that Malthusian practice is not of necessity sinful, and as he is urging the Church to remove a ban on that practice, it is necessary for him to prove in the first place that his opinion is right and that the teaching of the Church is wrong. Elsewhere in these pages I have stated the reasons why Christian morality brands the act of artificial birth control as intrinsically a sin, a malum in se, and those reasons have never been disproved by Lord Dawson or by anyone. His comparison between the use of contraceptives and eating or drinking is a false analogy. Eating is a natural act, not in itself sinful, whereas the use of contraceptives is an unnatural act, in itself a sin. The extent to which artificial birth control is practised neither increases nor diminishes the sinful nature of the act, but merely indicates the number of times the same sin is committed. Lord Dawson admits the danger of Neo-Malthusian methods being carried to excess, and counsels that these practices be used in moderation; but is it likely that those who have discarded the teaching of a Church and the dictates of the moral law will be seriously influenced by what he calls “an appeal to patriotism”?

    Now there is one appeal to patriotism which Lord Dawson could have made but did not make. He might have pleaded that for the sake of the nation all attempts at unnatural birth control amongst the wealthier and more leisured citizens should be abandoned forthwith, and that the lawful form should be confined to those few cases where limitation of the family is justified on genuine medical grounds. But he refrained from making that appeal, and his plea for the use of contraceptives in moderation is more likely to be quoted with approval in the boudoirs of Mayfair than in humbler homes.

    Lord Dawson's grave error in failing to anticipate the inevitable consequences of his deplorable speech is becoming more and more apparent. In the columns of The Daily Herald, cheek by jowl with advertisements concerning “Herbalists,” “Safe and Sure Treatment for Anaemia, Irregularities, etc.,” “Knowledge for Young Wives,” and “Surgical Goods and Appliances,” there appears the following notice:

        “Lord Dawson, the King's Physician, says, 'Birth control has come to
        stay.' Following up this honest and daring declaration, the Liberator
        League have decided to distribute 10,000 copies of its publications
        free to applicants sending stamped addressed envelopes to J.W. Gott,
        Secretary ... London, N.W.5.”

    A stamped addressed envelope brought in return sample copies of two undated newsprints, entitled The Rib Tickler and The Liberator, and, to the honour of newsvendors, we learn that these papers are “not supplied by newsagents.” The first print is devoted to Blasphemy, and the second to Birth Control. Both papers are edited by J.W. Gott, “of London, Leeds, Liverpool, and other prisons,” who, when he is not in jail for selling blasphemous or obscene literature, earns a livelihood by a propaganda of “Secularism, Socialism, and Neo-Malthusianism,” combined with the sale of contraceptives. At Birmingham in 1921 this individual, according to his own statement, was charged, on eleven summonses, with having sent “an obscene book” and “obscene literature” through the post, and with “publishing a blasphemous libel of and concerning the Holy Scriptures and the Christian Religion.” “The Malthusian League (at their own expense, for which I here wish to thank them) sent their Hon. Secretary, Dr. Binnie Dunlop, who gave evidence” ... that the Council of the Malthusian League ... “most strongly protests against the description of G. Hardy's book, How to prevent Pregnancy, as obscene, for that book gives in a perfectly refined and scientific way this urgently needed information.” This opinion was not shared by the jury, who brought in a verdict of guilty, and Gott was sentenced to six months' imprisonment. From the Liberator we learn that the Treasurer of the Liberator League was fined L20, having been found guilty on the following summons—“for that you on the eleventh day of September 1920, at the Parish of Consett, in the County aforesaid, unlawfully, wickedly, maliciously, and scandalously did sell to divers persons, whose names are unknown, in a public street, there situate, a certain lewd, wicked, scandalous, and obscene print entitled 'Large or Small Families,' against the Peace of our Sovereign Lord the King, His Crown and Dignity.”

    Lord Dawson's advice was indeed perilous because “the British Empire and all its traditions will decline and fall if the Motherland is faithless to motherhood”; [120] and the nation would do better to pay heed to the following words of His Majesty the King: “The foundations of national glory are in the homes of the people. They will only remain unshaken while the family life of our race and nation is strong, simple, and pure.”

    All Lord Dawson's arguments are hoary fallacies. “Once more, careful distinction needs to be made between”—anaesthetics and contraceptives. Anaesthetics assist the birth of a child, whereas contraceptives frustrate the act of procreation. The old explanation that man's progress has been achieved by harnessing and not by opposing the forces of nature is dismissed with ignominy. The age-long teaching of Hippocrates that the healing art was based on the Vis Medicatrix Naturae is overthrown by Lord Dawson of Penn, in a single sentence; and in place of the Father of Medicine as a guide to health of body and mind, there comes the King's Physician:

        “To pestle a poison'd poison behind his crimson lights.”

    When a great leader announces the birth of a new epoch, it is meet that the rank and file remain silent; and at this Congress of the Church of England no jarring interruptions marred the solemnity of the moment. No old-fashioned doctor was there to utter a futile protest, and there was no simple-minded clergyman to rise in the name of Christ and give Lord Dawson the lie. Without dissent, on a public platform of the Established Church, presided over by a Bishop, and in full view of the nation, “the moth-eaten mantle of Malthus, the godless robe of Bradlaugh, and the discarded garments of Mrs. Besant,” [121] were donned—by the successor of Lister. It was a proud moment for the birth controllers, but for that national institution called “Ecclesia Anglicana” a moment full of shame.

    [Footnote 100: British Medical Journal, August 6, 1921, p. 219.]

    [Footnote 101: There is, or perhaps we should say there was, a legacy of 1,000 Rhenish guilders awaiting anyone who, in the judgment of the faculty of law in the University of Heidelberg or of Bonn, is able to establish the fact that any Jesuit ever taught this doctrine or anything equivalent to it. Vide The Antidote, vol. iii, p. 125, C.T.S., London.]

    [Footnote 102: Gen. xxxviii. 9-10]

    [Footnote 103: Vide Catholic Times, August 27, 1921, p. 7.]

    [Footnote 104: The Army and Religion, 1919, p. 448.]

    [Footnote 105: Universe, November 4, 1921, p. 3.]

    [Footnote 106: Eighty-second Annual Report of the Registrar-General of England and Wales, 1919, p. xiv.]

    [Footnote 107: The Times, January 13, 1885.]

    [Footnote 108: British Medical Journal, November 19, 1921, p. 872.]

    [Footnote 109: British Medical Journal, November 26, 1921, p. 924]

    [Footnote 110: British Medical Journal, December 10, 1921, p. 1016.]

    [Footnote 111: Common Sense on the Population Question, p. 4]

    [Footnote 112: Dr. C.K. Millard, in The Modern Churchman, May 1919.]

    [Footnote 113: Reproduced in The Declining Birth-rate, 1916, p. 386.]

    [Footnote 114: Outspoken Essays, 1919, p. 75.]

    [Footnote 115: Report, p. 44.]

    [Footnote 116: Ibid., p. 112.]

    [Footnote 117: Evening Standard, October 12, 1921.]

    [Footnote 118: October 15, 1921.]

    [Footnote 119: Man and Superman, Act III, p. 125.]

    [Footnote 120: Sunday Express, October 16, 1921.]

    [Footnote 121: On becoming a Theosophist, Mrs. Besant retracted her approval of Neo-Malthusianism.]

    CHAPTER IX. THE TEACHING OF THE CATHOLIC CHURCH ON BIRTH CONTROL

    Section 1. A FALSE VIEW OF HER DOCTRINE

    One of the marks of the Catholic Church, whereby she may be distinguished from all other Churches, is that her teaching is always clear and above all logical. Yet this fact has not saved her teaching from misrepresentation in the hands of Malthusians. For example, Dr. C. Killick Millard writes as follows:

        “The Churches have taught that it was the divine wish that human beings
        should multiply and population increase—the more rapidly the better;
        the traditional authority for this being the instruction given to Noah
        and his family, after the Deluge, to 'be fruitful and multiply and
        replenish the earth.' The Churches have continued to teach that the
        duty of man was to obey the divine command and still to increase and
        multiply
    , and until recently any attempt by married couples to
        restrict or regulate the birth-rate was denounced as sinful.

        “This is still the orthodox attitude, I believe, of the Roman Catholic
        Church, with its celibate priesthood; but, as it is clearly useless to
        reason with those who claim infallibility, it is unnecessary to discuss
        the question further so far as Roman Catholicism is concerned.” [122]

    Now, although it may be unnecessary for Dr. Millard to discuss the question further, he will, I am sure, regret having inadvertently misstated the truth. The Catholic Church has never denounced as sinful “any attempt by married couples to restrict or regulate the birth-rate.” On the contrary, the Catholic Church has taught, by her greatest doctor, St. Thomas Aquinas, “that the essence of marriage is not primarily in the begetting of offspring, but in the indissoluble union between husband and wife.” [123]

    Section 2. THE ESSENCE AND PURPOSE OF MARRIAGE

    There is an obvious distinction between the essence of a thing and the ends or purposes for which the thing exists. For example, in a business partnership the essence of the partnership is a legal instrument, whereas the purposes or ends of the partnership are various commercial projects. The following is a clear statement, by Father Vincent McNabb, O.P., [124] of Catholic teaching concerning the nature and end of marriage:

        “Marriage is an indissoluble state of life wherein a man and a woman
        agree to give each other power over their bodies for the begetting,
        birth, and upbringing of offspring. The natural and primary end of
        marriage is this duty towards offspring. But, as sin has despoiled the
        human will and disturbed human relations, marriage has now the
        secondary end of allaying sexual lust.

        “But it is a principle of ethics that what is primary cannot be set
        aside as if it were secondary, nor can the secondary be sought as if it
        were primary. To invert the ethical order is to bring in that disorder
        which is called sin. If the human act brings in a slight disorder, it
        is venial sin; if the human act brings in a grievous disorder it is a
        grievous or mortal sin.

        “It is a grievous disorder, and, therefore, a grievous sin, to desire
        satisfaction in such sexual intercourse as could not result in the
        begetting of offspring.

        “As the wedded pair have given each other power over their bodies it
        would be a grave sin for one to refuse either altogether or for a
        considerable time the fulfilment of the marriage debt. But it is not a
        sin if by mutual agreement the wedded pair refrain from the marriage
        debt for a time, or for ever. As a rule, and speaking objectively, it
        would be heroic virtue for a wedded pair to abstain for a long time,
        and still more for ever, from the marriage debt. To counsel such a
        practice indiscriminately would be a sinful want of prudence, and, in a
        confessor, of professional knowledge.

        “It is quite clear that by mutual consent, even without any further
        motive, the wedded pair can abstain from marital intercourse. Still
        more may they abstain for a time or for ever, for a good motive, e.g.
        in order to have time for prayer, for good works, for bringing up such
        family as they already have to support.”

    Section 3. ARTIFICIAL STERILITY WHOLLY CONDEMNED

    Artificial birth control is an offence against the law of God, and is therefore forbidden by the Catholic Church. Any Catholic who wilfully adopts this practice violates the law of God in a serious matter, and is therefore guilty of mortal sin, an outrageous and deliberate insult offered by a human creature to the Infinite Majesty.

    The Catholic Church teaches that men and women should control the sex impulse just as they should control their appetite for food or drink. The principal end of marriage, as we have seen, is the purpose of its institution, the procreation and bringing up of children. The secondary end of marriage is mutual assistance and companionship, and a remedy against concupiscence. Where it is advisable, owing to the health of the mother or owing to reasons of prudence as distinct from selfishness, to limit the number of children, the Catholic Church points out that this should be done by the exercise of self-control, or by restricted use. As those who deny the possibility or even the wisdom of self-restraint are not likely to pay the slightest attention to the teaching of the Church, I will quote the opinions of two clear-thinking, non-Catholic writers.

    Mr. George Bernard Shaw has said:

        “I have no prejudices. The superstitious view of the Catholic Church is
        that a priest is something entirely different from an ordinary man. I
        know a great many Catholic priests, and they are men who have had a
        great deal of experience. They have at the back a Church which has had
        for many years to consider the giving of domestic advice to people. If
        you go to a Catholic priest and tell him that a life of sexual
        abstinence means a life of utter misery, he laughs. And obviously for a
        very good reason. If you go to Westminster Cathedral you will hear
        voices which sound extremely well, and very differently from the voices
        of the gentlemen who sing at music-halls, and who would not be able to
        sing in that way if they did not lead a life extremely different from
        the Catholic priest....

        “I may say that I am in favour of birth control. I am in favour of it
        for its own sake. I do not like to see any human being absolutely the
        slave of what we used to call 'Nature.' Every human action ought to be
        controlled, and you make a step in civilisation with something which
        has been uncontrollable. I am therefore in favour of control for its
        own sake. But when you go from that to the methods of control, that is
        a very different thing. As Dr. Routh said, we have to find out methods
        which will not induce people to declare that they cannot exist without
        sexual intercourse.” [125]

    Of course the use of contraceptives is the very negation of self-control.

    The late Sir William Osier, speaking of venereal disease, says:

        “Personal purity is the prophylaxis which we as physicians are
        especially bound to advocate. Continence may be a hard condition ...
        but it can be borne, and it is our duty to urge this lesson upon young
        and old who seek our advice on matters sexual.”

    Section 4. THE ONLY LAWFUL METHOD OF BIRTH CONTROL

    There are methods of control whereby people are enabled to exist, and to exist happily, without being slaves to the sex impulse. These methods are those of the Catholic Church. Her people are encouraged to take a higher and a nobler view of marriage, to overcome their egoism and selfishness, and to practise moderation and self-restraint in the lawful use of marital rights. The Church urges her people to strengthen their self-restraint by observing the penitential seasons, especially Lent; by fasting or by abstaining from flesh meat at other times, if necessary by abstaining from alcohol; and by seeking that supernatural help which comes to those who receive the Sacraments worthily. When all other deterrents fail, it is lawful, according to the teaching of the Church, for married people to limit intercourse to the mid-menstrual period, when, although conception may occur, it is less likely to occur than at other times.

    All other methods are absolutely and without exception forbidden. This limited use of marriage, which, as we have seen, is within the rights of the married, differs from all methods of artificial birth-control as day differs from night, because: [Reference: Explanation]

    (1) No positive or direct obstacle is used against procreation.

    (2) The intercourse is natural, in contradistinction to what is equivalent to self-abuse.

    (3) Self-restraint is practised in that the intercourse is limited to certain times.

    (4) There is no risk to mental or physical health.

    (5) There is no evil will to defeat the course of nature; at worst there is merely an absence of heroism.

    Even if the question be considered solely as a matter of physiology the difference between these methods is apparent. Physiologists and gynaecologists believe that in natural intercourse there is, apart from fertilisation, an absorption of certain substances into the system of the woman. The role of this absorption is at present obscure, but it obviously exists for a purpose; and it is permissible to speculate whether, under natural conditions of intercourse, there is not a mutual biological reaction that makes, amongst other things, for physical compatibility. Whatever be its purpose or explanation in the marvellous mechanism of nature, this absorption of vital substances is either hindered or is absolutely prevented by artificial methods of birth control; whereas, in the method permitted by the teaching of the Catholic Church there is no interference with a physiological process. Even those who fail, from their lack of training, to comprehend moral distinctions in this matter should be able to appreciate the difference between a method that is physiological and one that is unphysiological.

    There are thousands who know little of the Catholic or of any other faith, and thousands who believe the Catholic Church to be everything except what it is. These people have no infallible rule of faith and morals, and when confronted, as they now are, by a dangerous, insidious campaign in favour of birth control, they do not react consistently or at all. It was therefore thought advisable to issue this statement in defence of the position of the Catholic Church; but the reader should remember that the teaching of the Church on this matter is held by her members to be true, not merely because it agrees with the notions of all right-thinking men and women, not because it is in harmony with economic, statistical, social, and biological truth, but principally because they know this teaching to be an authoritative declaration of the law of God. The Ten Commandments have their pragmatic justification; they make for the good of the race; but the Christian obeys them as expressions of the Divine Will.

    Section 5. CONCLUSION

    Our declining birth-rate is a fact of the utmost gravity, and a more serious position has never confronted the British people. Here in the midst of a great nation, at the end of a victorious war, the law of decline is working, and by that law the greatest empires in the world have perished. In comparison with that single fact all other dangers, be they of war, of politics, or of disease, are of little moment. Attempts have already been made to avert the consequences by the partial endowment of motherhood and by a saving of infant life. Physiologists are now seeking among the endocrinous glands and the vitamines for a substance to assist procreation. “Where are my children?” was the question shouted yesterday from the cinemas. “Let us have children, children at any price,” will be the cry of to-morrow. And all these thoughts were once in the mind of Augustus, Emperor of the world from the Atlantic to the Euphrates, from Mount Atlas to the Danube and the Rhine.

    The Catholic Church has never taught that “an avalanche of children" should be brought into the world regardless of consequences. God is not mocked; as men sow, so shall they reap, and against a law of nature both the transient amelioration wrought by philanthropists and the subtle expediences of scientific politicians are alike futile. If our civilisation is to survive we must abandon those ideals that lead to decline. There is only one civilisation immune from decay, and that civilisation endures on the practical eugenics once taught by a united Christendom and now expounded almost solely by the Catholic Church.

    [Footnote 122: The Modern Churchman, May 1919.]

    [Footnote 123: Rev. Vincent McNabb, O.P., The Catholic Gazette, September 1921, p. 194]

    [Footnote 124: Ibid]

    [Footnote 125: Speech at the Medico-Legal Society, July 7, 1921.]

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    A.—GENERAL PUBLICATIONS

    Marriage and the Sex Problem. By Dr. F.W. Foerster. Translated by Margaret Booth, B. Sc., Ph.D. London, 1912.

    The Menace of the Empty Cradle. By Bernard Vaughan, S.J. London, 1917.

    Coffins or Cradles. By Sir James Marchant. 1916.

    Moral Principles and Medical Practice. By C. Coppens, S.J., and H. Spalding, S.J.

    The Family and the Nation. By W.C.D. Whetham and Mrs. Whetham. London, 1909.

    The Law of Births and Deaths. By Charles Edward Pell. London, 1921.

    The Declining Birth-rate. Report of the National Birthrate Commission. London, 1916.

    The Church and Labour (A Compendium of Official Utterances). Edited by John A. Ryan, LL.D., and Joseph Husslein, Ph.D. London, 1921.

    B.—CATHOLIC TRUTH SOCIETY PUBLICATIONS

    (Obtainable from 69, Southwark Bridge Road, S.E.1.)

    The Condition of the Working Classes. (The Encyclical Rerum Novarum.) By Pope Leo XIII. Edited by Mgr. Canon Parkinson, D.D. 6d.

    Social Questions and the Duty of Catholics. By C.S. Devas, M.A. 6d.

    (The Following are Twopence each.)

    Birth-rate, The Declining. By H. Thurston, S.J.

    Christian Democracy before the Reformation. By Cardinal Gasquet, O.S.B.

    Christian Democracy: Its Meaning and Aim. By C.S. Devas.

    Christian Womanhood.

    Church and Social Reformers, The. By the Bishop of Northampton.

    Conjugal Life, The Duties of. By Cardinal Mercier.

    Divorce. By the Bishop of Northampton.

    English Economics and Catholic Ethics. By M. Maher.

    Labour, The Church and. By Abbot Snow, O.S.B.

    Landlords, A Dialogue on. By R.P. Garrold, S.J.

    The Catholic Church and the Principle of Private Property. By Hilaire Belloc.

    Rome and the Social Question.

    Social Reform, Pope Pius X on.

    Social Sense, The: Its Decay and its Revival. By A.P. Mooney, M.D.

    Socialism, The Catholic Church and. By Hilaire Belloc.

    Socialism, An Examination of. By the same.

    Socialism, Some Ethical Criticisms of. By A.P. Mooney, M.D.

    Trade Unionism. By Henry Somerville.

    Woman in the Catholic Church. By H.F. Hall.

    The Church and Science. By Sir Bertram Windle, M.D., F.R.S., K.S.G. 7_s. 6_d.

    Twelve Catholic Men of Science. Edited by Sir Bertram Windle, M.D., F.R.S. Sir Dominic Corrigan—Thomas Dwight—Galvani—Lapparent —Laennec—Linacre—Mendel—Johannes Mueller—Pasteur—Secchi—Nicolaus Stenson—Vesalius. 2_s. 6_d.

    Facts and Theories. A Consideration of Some Biological Conceptions of To-day. By Sir Bertram Windle, M.D., F.R.S., K.S.G. 2_s.

    The Modernist. By Joseph Rickaby, S.J. 1_s.

    The World and Its Maker. By J. Gerard, S.J. 4_d.

    (The Following are Twopence each.)

    Anti-Catholic History: How it is written. By Hilaire Belloc.

    Darwinism, The Decline of. By Walter Sweetman.

    Evolution and Exact Thought. By J. Gerard, S.J.

    Freedom of Thought. By. J. Vance, M.A., Ph.D.

    Freethought, Modern. By J. Gerard, S.J., F.L.S.

    Haeckel and his Philosophy. By J. Gerard, S.J.

    Life, The Origin of. By J. Gerard, S.J., F.L.S.

    Positivism. By Joseph Rickaby, S.J.

    Rationalist Propaganda, The, and How it must be met. By J. Gerard, S.J.

    Rationalist, The (Joseph M'Cabe), as Prophet. By J. Keating, S.J.

    Science and Its Counterfeit. By J. Gerard, S.J.

    Science or Romance: The Game of Speculation. By J. Gerard, S.J.

    Scientific Facts and Scientific Hypotheses. By Sir Bertram Windle, M.D., F.R.S.

    Scientific Opinion, The Ebb and Flow of. By Sir Bertram Windle, M.D., F.R.S.

    Babylonia and Assyria. By A. Condamin, S.J.

    The Catholic Church. By Canon Gildea.

    France, Plain Words on Church and State in.

    France, The Real Authors of the Separation in. By O. Kellet, S.J.

    “Good Queen Bess,” The Days of. By William Cobbett.

    Kulturkampf, The. By Humphrey Johnson, B.A.

    Luther, Four Centuries of. By Canon William Barry, D.D.

    Mediaeval England, Catholic Faith and Practice in. By H.J. Kilduff.

    Monasteries, The Suppression of the English. By William Cobbett.

    The Pilgrim Fathers. By H. Thurston, S.J.

    Reformation, Social Effects of the. By William Cobbett.

    (Leaflets 3s. per 100.)

    Do Babies build Slums? By Halliday Sutherland, M.D.

    C.—CATHOLIC SOCIAL GUILD PUBLICATIONS

    (Obtainable from Catholic Social Guild, Oxford.)

    A Primer of Social Science. By Mgr. Parkinson. 3s. 6d.

    Prostitution: The Moral Bearings of the Problem. By M.F. and J.F. Foreword by the late Archbishop of Liverpool. 2s. 6d.

    The Church and Eugenics. (New and revised edition, 1921.) By T. Gerrard. 1s. 6d.

    The Christian Family. By Margaret Fletcher. 1s. 6d.

    Sweated Labour and the Trade Boards Act. Edited by T. Wright. 8d.

    Guild Socialism. A Criticism of the National Guild Theory. By Francis Goldwell. 6d.

    Elements of Housing. By C. Tigar, S.J. 6d.

    The Gospel and the Citizen. By C.C. Martindale, S.J. 4d.

    The Church and the Worker. By V.M. Crawford. 4d.

    Questions of the Day. By J. Keating, S.J., and S.A. Parker, O.S.B. 4d.

    Elements of Economics. By Lewis Watt, S.J. 4d.

    The Nation's Crisis. By Cardinal Bourne. 3d.

    The Catholic Attitude to the Ministry of Health. By J.B. McLaughlin, O.S.B., and A.P. Mooney, M.D. 2d.

    D.—FRENCH PUBLICATIONS

    La Depopulation de la France. Jacques Bertillon. 1911.

    La Population francaise. Levasseur. 1891.

    La Question de la Population. Leroy-Beaulieu.

    Depopulation et Civilisation. 1890. Arsene Dumont.

    Natalie. Dr. Bertillon Pere.